Measurement, Quantification, and Economic Analysis: Numeracy in Economics

By Ingrid H. Rima | Go to book overview

Chapter 13

The right person, in the right place, at the right time

How mathematical expectations came into macroeconomics

Bradley W. Bateman

Two of the stylized facts about modern macroeconomics are that Maynard Keynes invented it in 1936 with the publication of his General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money and that this basic apparatus was supplanted by the rational expectations revolution in the 1970s. While there is just enough substance behind each of these two myths for them to have become widespread, they hide as much as they reveal about the true evolution of ideas that led to modern macroeconomics. In particular, they hide the fact that Keynes was the first theorist to introduce an explicit analytical model of expectations into macroeconomics. Contrary to the canard begun by Paul Samuelson, in his obituary notice of Keynes, that the General Theory “paves the way for a theory of expectation, but it hardly provides one” (1946:320) it is actually the case that Keynes was the product of an intellectual tradition that had paved the way for a theory of expectation, but he ultimately had to provide it himself. 1


EXPECTATIONS IN THE CAMBRIDGE TRADITION

The need for a theory of expectations in the explanation of aggregate economic behavior was always implicit in the Cambridge tradition in which Keynes was trained. From the time of the “founding” of the school in 1885, when Alfred Marshall returned to Cambridge to take the chair of Political Economy, Cambridge theorists routinely explained the business cycle as the result of errors of optimism and pessimism on the part of businessmen. This explanation of the cycle actually dated from at least 1837 with Lord Overstone, and was formally adopted by Marshall and his wife, Mary Marshall, in 1879 with the publication of their Economics of Industry. There the Marshalls describe how confidence and “her magic wand” (p. 155) can excite businessmen’s expectations of profit and how these expectations ultimately end in a situation in which businessmen lose their confidence and a “trade storm” ensues. 2 Marshall repeated these arguments verbatim in his Principles (1890) and redeveloped them in Money, Credit and Commerce (1923) which was published shortly before his death.

-230-

Notes for this page

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this book

This book has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this book

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this page

Cited page

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited page

Bookmark this page
Measurement, Quantification, and Economic Analysis: Numeracy in Economics
Table of contents

Table of contents

Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this book

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen
/ 462

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Welcome to the new Questia Reader

The Questia Reader has been updated to provide you with an even better online reading experience.  It is now 100% Responsive, which means you can read our books and articles on any sized device you wish.  All of your favorite tools like notes, highlights, and citations are still here, but the way you select text has been updated to be easier to use, especially on touchscreen devices.  Here's how:

1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
2. Click or tap the last word you want to select.

OK, got it!

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.