Occupational Safety and Health: A Problem of Double or Single Moral Hazard

By Lanoie, Paul | Journal of Risk and Insurance, March 1991 | Go to article overview

Occupational Safety and Health: A Problem of Double or Single Moral Hazard


Lanoie, Paul, Journal of Risk and Insurance


Occupational Safety and Health: a Problem of Double or Single Moral Hazard

ABSTRACT

Following Cooper and Ross (1985), this article contributes to the literature by

developing a principal-agent approach to the effect of imperfect information on safety

in the workplace. Firms and workers can influence the probability of workplace

accidents by taking precautions. To the extent that a worker's precaution cannot be

observed by a firm, and vice versa, contract designing is a problem characterized by

moral hazard. Double and single moral hazard lead to nonoptimal levels of precaution

from firms and workers, but not necessarily to an underprovision of precaution.

Furthermore, it is shown that regulatory policies aimed at promoting safety in the

workplace (by inducing increases in the levels of precaution) may not be

welfare-improving.

Some authors, such as Thaler and Rosen (1976), allege that the presence of wage differentials for risky jobs implies that public regulation of occupational safety and health (OSH) is unnecessary. They argue that risk premiums in dangerous occupations are enough to compensate a worker in the case of an accident and to induce the socially optimal effort needed to reduce hazards.(1) This argument against regulation of safety in the workplace holds in a world of perfect markets and complete information. However, it breaks down with incomplete information or imperfect markets, and the literature on accident prevention(2) shows that nonoptimal situations can occur. For instance, there are externalities; Manga et al. (1981) argue that risk in the workplace leads to indirect costs that should be taken into account in the firm's decision concerning safety expenditures. An obvious example is the indirect health cost that a child incurs when a pregnant woman is at risk.

Problems of imperfect information in the "market of workplace accidents" have also drawn special attention. In particular, Oi (1974), Diamond (1977) and Rea (1981) postulate that workers are not well informed about safety levels prevailing in different firms. Since market outcomes are not efficient in this case, the effect of various policies such as mandatory insurance (workers' compensation) and safety regulation should be analyzed. Diamond and Oi argue that mandatory insurance is justified because it raises the expected utility of risk averse workers, while the enforcement of safety standards is required in order to improve the level of safety in the workplace, which is suboptimal when workers underestimate risk. In a different model, Rea (1981) shows that, when workers underestimate risk, mandatory insurance and safety regulation may have the perverse effect of reducing welfare and the level of safety. In particular, wages may be reduced with mandatory insurance and, as a result, the level of safety may fall because workers will attempt to substitute wages for safer jobs.(3) Carmichael (1986) disagrees with the "uncomfortably ad hoc" assumption that workers underestimate risk. He integrates imperfect information by exploring the role of a firm's reputation in repeated games. His model suggests that it takes time for workers to learn about changes in safety levels in a firm which leads, generally, to an underprovision of safety. In contrast with Rea, Carmichael is able to make unambiguous statements about the welfare-improving nature of government intervention related to OSH. Among other results, he shows that an increase in the level of compensation benefits received in accident cases leads to an unambiguous improvement in welfare.

This article contributes to the literature by working out a new approach to the effect that imperfect information has on safety in the workplace. In particular, the problems of double and single moral hazard are examined in the "market of workplace accidents". …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Occupational Safety and Health: A Problem of Double or Single Moral Hazard
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Welcome to the new Questia Reader

The Questia Reader has been updated to provide you with an even better online reading experience.  It is now 100% Responsive, which means you can read our books and articles on any sized device you wish.  All of your favorite tools like notes, highlights, and citations are still here, but the way you select text has been updated to be easier to use, especially on touchscreen devices.  Here's how:

1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
2. Click or tap the last word you want to select.

OK, got it!

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.