Health Care Policy Reform - in the Public Interest or for the Special Interests?

By Korves, Ross C. | Business Economics, April 1993 | Go to article overview

Health Care Policy Reform - in the Public Interest or for the Special Interests?


Korves, Ross C., Business Economics


CHANGE IN public policy on health care at the federal government and state government levels is one of the major public policy areas for 1993. Hundreds of plans have been proposed by various health care provider groups, representatives of consumer groups and elected officials. The claimed goal of these efforts is more access to needed care for more people at more reasonable prices.

If governments did not intervene in the health care delivery system in any manner, some amount of health care would be demanded by consumers of care with money to pay for care, and some amount of care would be offered by health care providers responding to the market demands of health care consumers. We could argue over how this market would operate and how much care would be consumed, but a market would exist without public policy on health care. The only reasons to have government intervention is to increase the quality, increase the quantity, lower the price and expand the number of people who could afford to have care. The 1993 debate about public policy on health care begins with the assumption that increased government intervention will lead to a more positive outcome than would occur without that additional intervention.

Public policy on health care, or any other issue, is not made solely by disinterested public servants toiling to improve the lot of the common man. Votes are made in the Congress and state legislatures by human beings who have their own opinions shaped by their personal experiences and the experiences of family and friends. Millions of dollars, perhaps billions, will be spent by providers and receivers of care to influence votes by our elected leaders.

Public policy on health care is made by compromising many different special interest views to the point that enough groups will not oppose an outcome so that it can command a majority vote. Public policy on health care will change when the pain associated with maintaining the status quo is greater than the pain caused by moving to new policies. Economists should be concerned for personal reasons, because the quality of our lives and the lives of people we care about will be influenced by who controls the money in the health care system. But business economists also need to watch this debate for two business reasons:

1. Business costs will be directly impacted by changes in health care policy. Employers with employer-based health care plans are already familiar with the costs of health care. These costs will be impacted by federal government-imposed minimum benefit requirements. Employers who do not provide health care plans may be required to provide a plan or pay a payroll tax to fund employee health benefits from a state or federal plan. Higher business taxes may be imposed to pay for expanded care for low-income families.

2. The outcome of the health care policy debate may establish new precedents on how businesses can use public policy to influence the cost of inputs. If businesses can use public policy to force suppliers of health care for employees to accept government set prices, could they do the same with other suppliers? Would washing machine manufacturers then try to use public policy to control the price of steel or plastic, or car rental companies use public policy to limit price increases on automobiles? By the historical accident of providing health care as a fringe benefit, businesses have been sucked into a much wider debate of government-set prices and standards.

THE ACCEPTED POLITICAL AGENDA

The debate on health care policy has already been shaped into a narrow debate over how to implement changes that have become part of the accepted political agenda. This agenda is articulated in many different ways, but basically it comes down to universal access, cost control and redistribution of who pays for care. All plans, regardless of how "marketed-based" or how much "government control," come back to those basic points, Goodman and Musgrave describe from a public choice economics perspective why that has happened:

".

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Health Care Policy Reform - in the Public Interest or for the Special Interests?
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Welcome to the new Questia Reader

The Questia Reader has been updated to provide you with an even better online reading experience.  It is now 100% Responsive, which means you can read our books and articles on any sized device you wish.  All of your favorite tools like notes, highlights, and citations are still here, but the way you select text has been updated to be easier to use, especially on touchscreen devices.  Here's how:

1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
2. Click or tap the last word you want to select.

OK, got it!

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.