Schoolhouse Socialism

By Rome, Gregory; Block, Walter | Journal of Instructional Psychology, March 2006 | Go to article overview

Schoolhouse Socialism


Rome, Gregory, Block, Walter, Journal of Instructional Psychology


Public schools are part and parcel of socialism. This system of economics does not function well. Not in the Soviet Union, and not in any industry in the United States, certainly including education. The present paper attempts to show that education is no exception to this general rule.

Key Words: privatization, private schools, public schools, education, school vouchers, educational socialism

**********

Public schools should not exist in America. Education is not a legitimate function of government. To make matters even worse, the state is a terribly inefficient manager of anything; the classroom is no exception. Despite the mountains of cash and a staggering number of human lives invested in teaching American children in public schools, the endeavor has been an abysmal failure. As such, government education should be seen as the cancer on society that it really is and removed (1). Some proponents of school vouchers have put this plan forward as a means to this noble end, but government subsidy of schools--even of this sort--will have the very opposite effect: it will not lead to greater freedom in the educational arena, but at best only to more efficient educational socialism.

Let us explore why government education is illegitimate. As a first offense, it is funded by coercive taxation (2). Under pain of incarceration, American citizens are shaken down daily to fund the system. Because of this indiscriminate taxation, a significant portion of those footing the bill for public education will never partake of any part of the services provided with these ill-gotten gains; they are forced to pay for the schooling of other people's children. The state tramples on the property rights of every taxpayer funding their equal-opportunity dream. However, this is hardly the only coercion employed in this arena.

Once upon a time, some government hireling decided that the state knew better than any parent under its dominion how and what to teach their children. They made attendance at some recognized educational institution compulsory for every school-aged child. As a result, the government gets to define what a school is and what it teaches; Big Brother is more than happy to do so, because he then gets to dictate the curriculum of any organization begging for the seal of approval. Parents--already taxed to fund a government school system to compensate for their obvious inability to teach their own offspring--are coerced a second time, now forced to educate their progeny according to the state's whim. Again, their rights are trampled. It is for everyone's good to educate the youth, right?

There is an unconscionable conflict of interest at work here. As Young and Block (1999) put it, "The individuals entrenched in positions of power in the state are those who control over what children are taught concerning history, government, economics, and so forth. The result is a citizenry educated by the operators of the state on how to choose the operators of the state!"

Also, the endeavor is not a public good, which can be defined as a one that is "neither excludable nor rival" (Mankiw, 225). For a service to qualify as a public good, it must be impossible to exclude anyone from consuming it once it is produced, and no one person's consumption of the good can detract from any other person's. How does education fare under this test? It is most certainly rival. Therefore, it fails on that one ground. For one thing, if the money is spent on schooling, it is unavailable for anything else. For another, the argument on the part of mainstream economists is that even childless people benefit from the education of other people's children due to the "market failure" of external economies. If these other children are schooled (not the same as educated, but let that pass), then they will be less likely to be criminals, more likely to be gainfully employed, vote intelligently, etc. Since these benefits undoubtedly accrue to all, goes the argument, everyone ought to be forced to pay.

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Schoolhouse Socialism
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Welcome to the new Questia Reader

The Questia Reader has been updated to provide you with an even better online reading experience.  It is now 100% Responsive, which means you can read our books and articles on any sized device you wish.  All of your favorite tools like notes, highlights, and citations are still here, but the way you select text has been updated to be easier to use, especially on touchscreen devices.  Here's how:

1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
2. Click or tap the last word you want to select.

OK, got it!

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.