Remembering the Man Behind Rational Expectations: John Muth (1930-2005)

By Brannon, Ike | Regulation, Spring 2006 | Go to article overview

Remembering the Man Behind Rational Expectations: John Muth (1930-2005)


Brannon, Ike, Regulation


FEW IDEAS HAVE HAD AS MUCH OF AN effect on the science of economics as the concept of rational expectations. The idea is deceivingly simple: Buyers and sellers who need to guess future prices do not merely assume that they will be the same as previous prices. Instead, they use all available information to make an educated guess as to what prices will be--at least when it is worth their while to do so. What is more, the educated guess will, on average, be correct. People will not consistently make mistakes when it comes to prognosticating future prices.

This elementary notion, first formulated by the economist John Muth, ultimately upended four decades of economic research on macroeconomics and monetary policy, utterly discrediting the notion that governments can simply fiddle with the money supply and inflation rate to achieve the desired rate of unemployment. New Fed chairman Ben Bernanke's stated desire to target inflation to between one and two percent, a policy that seems quite sensible today, would have sounded foolish only 30 years ago.

Eventually, the bulk of what came to be considered as mainstream "Keynesian" economics, with its emphasis on the need for governments to play an active role in the economy, was jettisoned. Robert Lucas, the economist who popularized the idea of rational expectations, received the Nobel Prize for his efforts.

Despite the impact of Muth's idea, the honor and glory ultimately accorded by the profession for this titanic idea skipped by him with nary a nod in his direction. John Muth passed away last October 25th at the age of 75, and if the lack of honor and glory bothered him, he never let on. Muth, a shy and socially awkward man, would have found the attention and fuss that goes with a Nobel Prize pure torture.

THE LIFE OF JOHN MUTH

Muth grew up in the Midwest, with his family eventually settling in St. Louis. He attended Washington University in St. Louis, where he studied industrial engineering, and in 1952 he went to Carnegie Tech in Pittsburgh to study mathematical economics. At the time, Carnegie Tech was the place to be for young academics studying quantitative economics. Future Nobel laureates Herb Simon, Merton Miller, and Franco Modigliani were on the faculty, and John Nash, the game theorist who won the prize in 1984 and whose life story was the subject of the movie A Beautiful Mind, had finished his undergraduate degree a couple years earlier. Future Nobel winners Ed Prescott and Robert Lucas arrived later in Muth's tenure there.

Muth excelled at Carnegie; Modigliani, his adviser, called him "a very original and talented man." Modigliani, with whom Muth did a good bit of his research, also commented upon Muth's eccentricity, remarking that "he seemed to take pains to appear as an oddball." Muth quickly went from graduate student to professor before taking the Ph.D., and it was there that he conceived of and published his research on rational expectations.

The first paper he published in this area, entitled "Rational Expectations and the Theory of Price Movements," appeared in Econometrica in 1961. The paper was little noted at the time of its release, and one of the referees fought against its publication, claiming it was of little consequence. A companion piece appeared in The Journal of the American Statistical Association around the same time

It was not until a decade after publication that other economists began to recognize the importance of Muth's idea, after it was incorporated into a paper by Bob Lucas and Leonard Rapping. By that time, Muth had left Carnegie, first to Michigan State and then to Indiana University.

Much like Nash, who abandoned his work on game theory shortly after graduation after its lack of acclaim forced him to "settle" for a job at MIT, Muth soon abandoned work on rational expectations. He once confided that after his Econometrica article came out, he had assumed that he would be able to go anywhere he wanted, but no one paid it much attention. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Remembering the Man Behind Rational Expectations: John Muth (1930-2005)
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Welcome to the new Questia Reader

The Questia Reader has been updated to provide you with an even better online reading experience.  It is now 100% Responsive, which means you can read our books and articles on any sized device you wish.  All of your favorite tools like notes, highlights, and citations are still here, but the way you select text has been updated to be easier to use, especially on touchscreen devices.  Here's how:

1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
2. Click or tap the last word you want to select.

OK, got it!

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.