Self-Fulfilling Fed

The Washington Times (Washington, DC), March 12, 2007 | Go to article overview

Self-Fulfilling Fed


Byline: Alfred Tella, SPECIAL TO THE WASHINGTON TIMES

In economics, sometimes believing makes it so. When people are optimistic about the economic outlook, they behave in ways that help realize their expectations.

If consumers are confident about their future incomes and don't foresee higher taxes or inflation, they are more willing to make spending commitments. The stronger demand for goods and services in turn stimulates business investment, job creation, and wage growth, further fortifying economic optimism. Pessimism about the future can be similarly self-fulfilling.

Economic expectations are influenced by personal experience, past trends and forecasts. Especially influential are the forecasts made public by the Federal Reserve's policymaking open market committee (FOMC).

Take inflation. When the FOMC forecasts continued price stability, it is influencing the public's expectations and behavior in a way that helps to assure that outcome. Optimism has its payoffs. If inflation were to get away from the Fed and policymakers to lose credibility, expectations of worsening inflation could trigger behavior that would contribute to bringing about that result.

Twice a year the Fed chairman presents to the Congress the FOMC's economic forecast for the current and following year, which includes the committee's prediction of inflation. In the last seven years, the FOMC has twice changed the inflation measure used in its forecasts, both times shifting to a tamer inflation series.

In the years prior to 2000, the FOMC forecast the overall, or headline, Consumer Price Index (CPI). In early 2000, during rising inflation, the FOMC shifted from the CPI to forecasting the more subdued overall personal consumption expenditure (PCE) price index. During the 1990s, the PCE inflation rate had averaged about a half point less per year than the CPI inflation rate, not a small amount.

The explanation for the switch was relegated to a footnote in the Fed's report to Congress, though the reasons given were substantive: The CPI was upward biased because it used fixed weights, whereas the PCE inflation rate reflected the changing composition of spending, was a more comprehensive measure, and was more consistent over time.

The second change came in mid-2004, again when inflation was rising. The FOMC switched from forecasting the total PCE to forecasting core PCE inflation, which excludes food and energy prices, some of which are volatile and can distort the trend in underlying inflation. In the decade prior to the change, the core PCE inflation rate had averaged about a half-point less a year than the total PCE rate. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Self-Fulfilling Fed
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.