Minimizing Missed Opportunities: A New Model of Choice?

By Oleinik, Anton | Journal of Economic Issues, June 2007 | Go to article overview

Minimizing Missed Opportunities: A New Model of Choice?


Oleinik, Anton, Journal of Economic Issues


Key axioms of the "hard core" of neoclassical theory suggest that there is a solid link between the model of rational choice and the existence of unique, stable and Pareto-efficient market equilibrium. The task of this article consists of differentiating two potential sources of sub-optimal outcomes; the first refers to the nature of individual choice, and the second--to interactions between agents, with special emphasis on the latter.

Power relationships produce an asymmetrical situation: one side, Principal, tries to realize his or her agenda, whereas the other side, Agent, chooses between sub-optimal outcomes. One of the strategies for imposing Principal's will, domination by virtue of a constellation of interests in the market, is the subject of the present analysis. Max Weber, who first introduced the concept (1968, 943-946), does not explore it in depth--he just mentions that this type of domination is more oppressive to Agent than the will Principal imposed by legitimizing it.

Monopoly power illustrates this form of domination. Neoclassical economists show how monopoly leads to sub-optimal outcomes at the macro level. Nevertheless, they appear less interested in modifications in the model of individual choice induced by monopoly and in the interactive side of relationships between Principal (monopolist) and Agent.

Part I is devoted to differentiating the two sources of sub-optimal outcomes. Power is considered as one of the coordination mechanisms. A special case of power, domination by virtue of a constellation of interests (DVCI), is discussed in Part II. It involves minimizing Agent's missed opportunities. Empirical examples considered in Part III illustrate the idea of DVCI. They refer to recent tendencies in emerging markets in post-Soviet countries.

Sources of Sub-optimal Outcomes: Individual Decision Making versus Interactions

Particularities of approaches developed, on one hand by the majority of economists, and, on the other by game theorists and advocates of the old institutionalism, facilitate the task of differentiating sources of sub-optimality. The former group focuses attention on individual decision making, whereas the latter questions the premise of methodological individualism and examines interactions.

With the help of the model of bounded rationality, mainstream economists (Simon 1978) indicate that limited cognitive capacities and high transaction costs prevent the agent from finding and implementing an optimal solution. Uncertainty, or unawareness of all possible "states of nature," further complicate the task of finding the optimum (Langlois 1986, 228). Socio-economists introduce values into analysis. The eventual conflict between values and rational considerations calls for ordering preferences. Values, as second-order preferences, can "overrule" first-order preferences referring to the model of rational choice and lead to sub-optimal--in terms of technical expedience--outcomes (Jonge 2005).

Models of rational choice remain focused on individual decision-making. In spite of the existence of various institutionalist interpretations of bounded rationality, they just add constraints under which an individual attempts to maximize his/her utility (Figure 1).

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

The search for an alternative source of sub-optimal outcomes involves shifting the unit of analysis "from commodities and individuals to transactions" (Commons 1931, 652). Sub-optimality due to coordination failures takes manifest forms if in order to achieve desired outcomes, everyone needs to adjust their behavior to that of their counterparts--yet fails to interpret correctly their intentions and to send them an easily decipherable signal about his or her own intentions (Schelling 1960, Ch. 3; Schotter 1981, 22-23). For example, each of two motorists on a narrow road depends on the counterpart's choice to achieve the ultimate goal of avoiding a collision. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Minimizing Missed Opportunities: A New Model of Choice?
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.