Health Reform and the Legal-Economic Nexus

By Langbert, Mitchell; Murphy, Frederick | Journal of Economic Issues, June 1995 | Go to article overview

Health Reform and the Legal-Economic Nexus


Langbert, Mitchell, Murphy, Frederick, Journal of Economic Issues


In this paper, we interpret the health system's litany of problems, including high costs, lack of access, inequality, and reform's repeated failure, in terms of institutionalist theory about the legal-economic nexus. The litany of problems is indeed intractable. With respect to costs, for example, in 1993 health expenditures in the United States were 14.4 percent of real per capita gross national product, 40 percent more than in Canada, which has the second highest level of spending.(1) Nevertheless, mortality rates in the United States have been worse than average for the industrialized world. Some reasons are that a relatively small part of the population is responsible for a large share of health spending; that administration costs are higher than other countries; that entrenched and inefficient third-party financing methods stimulate demand, encouraging unnecessary care and excessive spending; that 37 million uninsured Americans are likely to delay care and face more expensive and less effective emergency care; and that providers have overinvested in technology.

These can be interpreted as empirical consequences of the legal-economic nexus, which Samuels [1989] defines as the interaction of law and economy to distribute wealth among interests in accordance with a collective bargaining process that reflects history, custom, and ideology as well as economic power.

Our claim is that although President Clinton's 1993 health reform bill aimed to placate traditional health interests, its failure ensued from a fragmentation of power that evolved out of large corporations' and insurance companies' cost containment programs. These programs have shifted costs from large to small firms. In 1994, small business lobbies responded by stalling reform. But corporate cost containment efforts themselves have responded to traditional health lobbies' earlier success in inhibiting reform; the system's evolution explains reform's failure.

The History of Health Reform

Two themes emerge from the history of health reform in the United States. The first is the ability of vested interests to frustrate reform proposals. The second is their use of direct ideological appeals in doing so.

The earliest important push for reform took place in the 1910s, when the American Association for Labor Legislation (A.A.L.L.) drafted a model health bill that favored a decentralized system of jointly managed and locally regulated health insurance trust funds [Numbers 1978).(2) Despite initial support from the leadership of the American Medical Association (A.M.A.), rank-and-file physicians opposed the proposal because they feared encroachment on their professional autonomy. With the approach of World War I, the physicians identified national health insurance with kaiserism in direct public appeals.(3) Private insurance companies, the National Association of Manufacturers, and Samuel Gompers's American Federation of Labor, which feared encumbrance of collective bargaining, joined the assault, and the A.A.L.L.'s proposal was defeated [Skocpol 1993].

In 1926, the Committee on the Costs of Medical Care (C.C.M.C.), endorsing group practice and private insurance, made a modest attempt at health reform, and the A.M.A. again opposed it [Starr 1983]. In fact, the A.M.A. opposed private and public health insurance, calling insurance "socialism and Communism-inciting to revolution" [Weeks and Berman 1985]]. Then, during the Roosevelt administration, the A.M.A. aborted a third attempt at health insurance reform [Hirshfield 1970]. In this campaign, the A.M.A. reversed its earlier opposition to private insurance in order to preempt support for public insurance ["Progress of Plans for Economic Security" 1935]. When the Roosevelt administration's proposal for national health insurance was released in 1938, the A.M.A., joined by state and local medical societies and individual physicians, again lobbied strenuously, and Roosevelt backed down. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Health Reform and the Legal-Economic Nexus
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Welcome to the new Questia Reader

The Questia Reader has been updated to provide you with an even better online reading experience.  It is now 100% Responsive, which means you can read our books and articles on any sized device you wish.  All of your favorite tools like notes, highlights, and citations are still here, but the way you select text has been updated to be easier to use, especially on touchscreen devices.  Here's how:

1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
2. Click or tap the last word you want to select.

OK, got it!

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.