Arbitration and Salary Gaps in Major League Baseball

By Gustafson, Elizabeth; Hadley, Lawrence | Quarterly Journal of Business and Economics, Summer 1995 | Go to article overview

Arbitration and Salary Gaps in Major League Baseball


Gustafson, Elizabeth, Hadley, Lawrence, Quarterly Journal of Business and Economics


INTRODUCTION

Prior to 1973 the labor market for major league baseball players was dominated by the reserve clause. This clause restricted a player's labor market activity to the team holding his contract in the previous season. Because major league teams were not permitted to compete for each other's players, they enjoyed the advantage of a pure monopsonist in dealing with their own players. Economic theory predicts that profit-maximizing monopsonists will exploit workers by paying a wage rate below marginal revenue product. This prediction is based upon the standard textbook analysis of monopsonists who face marginal resource cost functions rising above their labor supply functions. Scully (1974) uses a recursive econometric model to estimate the magnitude of this exploitation. He finds the losses of the baseball players to be considerable.

Since 1973 there have been two dramatic changes in this labor market. First, in 1973 players and owners voluntarily agreed to use binding final offer arbitration to settle salary disputes. At the time, this appeared to be a harmless concession from the owners' viewpoint. The Curt Flood lawsuit challenging the reserve clause recently had been decided in the owners' favor and had been upheld by the Supreme Court.(1) The clause seemed solidly entrenched as a permanent part of baseball's labor market. The owners had every reason to expect that arbitrators would observe only salaries suppressed by the existing labor market and that these salaries would set the boundaries of their awards.

Second, grievance arbitration overturned the reserve clause in 1975, and major league baseball entered the free agent era. Players currently become eligible for arbitration just before reaching three years of major league service(2) and become eligible for free agency after six years of service.(3)

The combination of free agency and binding salary arbitration has proven to be advantageous for veteran players, as indicated by the upward explosion in their salaries over the past 15 years. Our research has documented a large one time salary increment at the time that players become eligible for arbitration. This salary jump suggests that arbitrators have succeeded in making salary awards that are at least commensurate with those of free agents (Hadley and Gustafson, 1991). The result of this market structure is a salary gap between the players who are eligible for arbitration and those who are ineligible, suggesting that ineligible players may continue to suffer from monopsonistic exploitation.

While the salaries of players eligible for arbitration are definitely higher than the salaries of ineligible players, it could be argued that the difference is due at least partly to improved performance of experienced players and seniority effects rather than exploitation. To isolate the portion of the salary difference that is due to a different reward structure rather than due to different performance, this paper presents a gap analysis for hitters and for pitchers. The portion of the gap between earnings of average eligible and ineligible players explained by their performance and their years of service in the major leagues is justifiable in the context of a competitive labor market. In contrast, the remaining unexplained portion of the gap is interpreted as a measure of exploitation of the arbitration-ineligible players. It should be recognized that important variables omitted from the earnings equations also will contribute to this portion of the gap.

Scoville (1974) hypothesizes that star players will be less exploited than average players because the supply of star players is inelastic. Hill (1985) finds evidence that stars are more exploited than are average players. To pursue this open question we have done a gap analysis for certain groups of above average players.

One may expect an increase in earnings when players become eligible for free agency after six years of service rather than when they become eligible for arbitration at about three years of service.

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Arbitration and Salary Gaps in Major League Baseball
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Welcome to the new Questia Reader

The Questia Reader has been updated to provide you with an even better online reading experience.  It is now 100% Responsive, which means you can read our books and articles on any sized device you wish.  All of your favorite tools like notes, highlights, and citations are still here, but the way you select text has been updated to be easier to use, especially on touchscreen devices.  Here's how:

1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
2. Click or tap the last word you want to select.

OK, got it!

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.