The Optimal Size of a Religious Congregation: An Economic Theory of Clubs Analysis

By Zaleski, Peter; Zech, Charles | The American Journal of Economics and Sociology, October 1995 | Go to article overview

The Optimal Size of a Religious Congregation: An Economic Theory of Clubs Analysis


Zaleski, Peter, Zech, Charles, The American Journal of Economics and Sociology


I

Introduction

Religious congregations, in addition to their spiritual impact, are an important economic force in the United States. The Independent Sector (1988) has estimated that there are over 300,000 religious congregations in this country, and their combined annual revenue exceeds $50 billion. Almost all of their income comes from charitable contributions from congregation members. Much of their revenue is used to provide goods and services to the membership. Biddle (1992) has estimated that American congregations spend 71% of their income on activities that only benefit their membership. These congregations can be regarded as mutual benefit organizations, not unlike country clubs or other social clubs. They are quite appropriately analyzed by an economic theory of clubs model.

As clubs, religious congregations have an optimal size in terms of their number of members. The purpose of this study is to determine the optimal size of congregations for four different denominations. The optimal size of a congregation will be defined as the number of members that maximizes total contributions. While most religious congregations would surely argue that their goals have little or nothing to do with maximizing contributions, economists recognize that people's willingness to pay for a good (even through philanthropy) serves as a valuable measure of their satisfaction with that good.

This is especially true since religious congregations exhibit a rare combination in the nonprofit sector: mutual benefit activities supported by voluntary contributions. Moreover, religious congregations must compete for members, since participation is voluntary. Therefore, the market test of people's willingness to pay for the services of their congregation through voluntary contributions is an appropriate one.

This study considers the optimal size in terms of maximizing contributions, rather than minimizing costs. There is an historical justification for this. During the early and mid 20th century, the concept of an optimal-sized congregation was a key concern among Protestant church leaders in the United States. Madison (1986) describes the movement among church reformers at the turn of the century to reduce costs by combining small rural congregations into fewer, larger congregations. Finke and Stark (1992) indicate that the same debate took place at mid-century concerning small suburban churches. In both cases, the reform movement was unsuccessful. It was rejected by churchgoers who derived utility from a sense of commitment that would be greatly diminished if they were forced to become members of larger congregations. Churchgoers' objections exhibited a belief in an optimal size based upon maximizing individual utility rather than minimizing average cost. The approach taken in this paper is consistent with that viewpoint.

In the following sections, religious congregations will be analyzed as clubs. A club-theoretic model will be described. A mathematical model of a congregation's contributions and optimal size is then developed and tested. The empirical results will be analyzed to determine the optimal congregation size for the following denominations: Roman Catholic, United Methodist, Lutheran, and Episcopalian. As described below, differences in denominational attitudes toward church attendance, policies regarding the creation of new congregations, the relative surplus or shortage of clergy, and other denominational polity issues could all result in different congregational optimal sizes for these denominations.

II

Religious Congregations as Clubs

The economic theory of clubs literature is well developed and will only be briefly summarized here (see Cornes and Sandler, 1986 and Sandler 1992). It suffices to say that the three most important characteristics of clubs are that they must be voluntary, involve sharing, and have the ability to exclude "free riders."

By this description, U. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

The Optimal Size of a Religious Congregation: An Economic Theory of Clubs Analysis
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Welcome to the new Questia Reader

The Questia Reader has been updated to provide you with an even better online reading experience.  It is now 100% Responsive, which means you can read our books and articles on any sized device you wish.  All of your favorite tools like notes, highlights, and citations are still here, but the way you select text has been updated to be easier to use, especially on touchscreen devices.  Here's how:

1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
2. Click or tap the last word you want to select.

OK, got it!

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.