New Keynesian Economics and the Phillips Curve

By Roberts, John M. | Journal of Money, Credit & Banking, November 1995 | Go to article overview

New Keynesian Economics and the Phillips Curve


Roberts, John M., Journal of Money, Credit & Banking


Sticky prices are an important part of monetary models of business cycles. In recent years, a consensus has formed around the microfoundations of sticky price models, and this consensus is an important part of New Keynesian economics (Ball, Mankiw, and Romer 1988). In this paper, I show that several of the New Keynesian models, including the models of staggered contracts developed by Taylor (1979, 1980) and Calvo (1983) and the quadratic price adjustment cost model of Rotemberg (1982), have a common formulation that is similar to the expectations-augmented Phillips curve of Friedman and Phelps.

I also present new estimates of this common model. Because prices are sticky in the New Keynesian models, price setting must take into account future prices, and an important issue in estimation is how to deal with expectations about future prices. Previous estimates of these models, such as those by Taylor (1980, 1989) and Rotemberg (1982), have been based on full-information techniques, in which expectations are solved under the assumption of rational expectations. As is well known, full-information estimation has the advantage of econometric efficiency if the model is correctly specified, but the disadvantage that if any part of the model is misspecified--even a part of secondary interest--the estimates will be inconsistent.

I explored two limited-information approaches. One was the technique, introduced by McCallum (1976), of using the actual future value of a variable as a proxy and then restricting the information used in estimation--such as any instrumental variables--to what was available at the time the expectations of the variable were formed. This approach has the advantage over the full-information technique that the complete economic environment need not be specified.

The other limited-information approach was to use inflation expectations obtained through surveys as proxies for expectations. This approach shares with McCallum's technique the advantage that assumptions about the structure of the rest of the economy are not necessary. But survey responses may be better measures of people's expectations than are realized future prices: I find that the key parameters of the model had the correct sign regardless of the proxy for expectations, but that the estimates were more precise when I use the surveys as proxies for expectations.

1. THE MODEL

In the New Keynesian literature, models of sticky prices have been grouped into two general categories: "time-dependent" and "state-dependent" models (Ball, Mankiw, and Romer 1988). In state-dependent models, firms change prices when underlying determinants, such as demand and costs, reach certain bounds. In time-dependent models, such as the staggered contracts models of Taylor and Calvo, firms set their prices for fixed periods of time. As I will show shortly, time-dependent models can have explicit closed-form solutions relating current price changes to future price changes and the current state of demand. State-dependent models do not, in general, have simple closed-form solutions, and in some state-dependent models, such as the one analyzed by Caplin and Spulber (1987), aggregate price adjustment may be instantaneous even if individual prices are sticky. As a consequence, I focus on time-dependent models.

1a. The Quadratic Price Adjustment Cost Model

In Rotemberg's (1982) framework, firms minimize the costs of changing prices, weighed against the costs of being away from the price the firm would choose in the absence of adjustment costs:(1)

(1) [Mathematical Expression Omitted]

where [omega] is total cost, p is the log of the actual price at time t, [p.sup.*] is the (log of the) price a firm would charge in the absence of adjustment costs, [theta] is a constant discount factor, and c is a parameter that measures the ratio of the costs of changing prices to the costs of being away from the optimum price.

The first-order condition of this problem is

(2) [Mathematical Expression Omitted]

Assume that the discount rate, [theta], is equal to one; for high frequency data, this is approximately correct.

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

New Keynesian Economics and the Phillips Curve
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Welcome to the new Questia Reader

The Questia Reader has been updated to provide you with an even better online reading experience.  It is now 100% Responsive, which means you can read our books and articles on any sized device you wish.  All of your favorite tools like notes, highlights, and citations are still here, but the way you select text has been updated to be easier to use, especially on touchscreen devices.  Here's how:

1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
2. Click or tap the last word you want to select.

OK, got it!

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.