Taxation and Intergenerational Transfers with Family Size Heterogeneity: Do Parents with More Children Prefer Higher Taxes?

By Hess, Gregory D.; Orphanides, Athanasios | Journal of Money, Credit & Banking, May 1996 | Go to article overview
Save to active project

Taxation and Intergenerational Transfers with Family Size Heterogeneity: Do Parents with More Children Prefer Higher Taxes?


Hess, Gregory D., Orphanides, Athanasios, Journal of Money, Credit & Banking


An important question in macroeconomics and public finance is whether the intertemporal allocation of tax revenue necessary to finance government expenditures affects household decisions. Recent attention has centered around the hypothesis that financing expenditures with current taxes is equivalent to deficit financing - the Ricardian equivalence hypothesis. As presented by Barro (1974), Ricardian equivalence predicts that a representative household should be indifferent between bond and tax financing of a fixed stream of government liabilities.(1) With a homogeneous population, the result implies that aggregate consumption does not respond to a current cut in taxes.

The hypothesis, however, rests on several assumptions that have been challenged both at the theoretical and empirical front. Evidence from aggregate data suggests that tax reductions have a positive impact on aggregate consumption - a Keynesian propensity.(2) At the theoretical front, the hypothesis has been shown to fail in the presence of tax related distortions. inoperative bequest motives, nonaltruistic bequest motives, imperfect loan markets. nondiversifiable income risk, stochastic mortality and fertility heterogeneity in income, wealth or abilities and other conditions.(3)

However, the theoretical failure of tax neutrality at the aggregate level often does not yield a Keynesian propensity to consume. With respect to nondiversifiable income risk, for instance, a Keynesian propensity obtains with proportional income taxation and uncertain income but the converse is true for lump-sum taxation with uncertain incidence (see Chan 1983). With respect to wealth heterogeneity and bequest taxation, a Keynesian propensity is obtained with progressive taxation but neutrality is maintained with a linear tax (Abel 1986). A common argument in support port of the Ricardian equivalence hypothesis is that even if the presence of heterogeneity creates non-neutralities at the household level because of the redistribution of the tax burden. in the aggregate approximate neutrality may, still be obtained.(4)

In this paper, we examine the implications of heterogeneity regarding family size for individual household behavior and for Ricardian equivalence in the aggregate. Using a dynastic model of intergenerational linkages. we show that the expected size of the dynastic family relative to the average family in the economy serves as an index of the strength of its intergenerational link to future generations. Heterogeneity in family size leads to conflicting preferences across households over the intertemporal allocation of taxes, with households with larger expected families in favor of a rise in current taxes. A current increase in the size of the government debt falls disproportionately, on dynasties with stronger intergenerational links. Since the incidence of taxes is per capita, those dynasties with more children pay a disproportionately large share of accumulated debt. Intergenerational differences in the size of the dynasty have intragenerational effects - redistributing wealth at a point in time across families of different size.(5) Notably this result relies only on dynastic intergenerational budget accounting and holds independently of the specifics of household preferences.

Further, aggregation over the heterogeneous responses to a tax cut results in a Keynesian propensity to consume. Importantly, this appears despite the absence of any sources of friction, and despite Ricardian behavior within each individual dynasty. A simple calculation using the frequency distribution of family size for the United States indicates that an increase in consumption of about 20 cents for every $1 in tax cuts can be reasonably expected without introducing any frictions such as distortionary taxes or inoperative bequest motives.

The intuition for this result is as follows. Consider a reduction in current taxes which redistributes resources from large families to small families.

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
Loading One moment ...
Project items
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

Cited article

Taxation and Intergenerational Transfers with Family Size Heterogeneity: Do Parents with More Children Prefer Higher Taxes?
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

While we understand printed pages are helpful to our users, this limitation is necessary to help protect our publishers' copyrighted material and prevent its unlawful distribution. We are sorry for any inconvenience.
Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

Cited passage

Welcome to the new Questia Reader

The Questia Reader has been updated to provide you with an even better online reading experience.  It is now 100% Responsive, which means you can read our books and articles on any sized device you wish.  All of your favorite tools like notes, highlights, and citations are still here, but the way you select text has been updated to be easier to use, especially on touchscreen devices.  Here's how:

1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
2. Click or tap the last word you want to select.

OK, got it!

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.

Are you sure you want to delete this highlight?