Beer Cans, Gas Guzzlers and Green Taxes: How Using Tax Instead of Law May Affect Environmental Policy

By Macdonald, Doug | Alternatives Journal, July-August 1996 | Go to article overview
Save to active project

Beer Cans, Gas Guzzlers and Green Taxes: How Using Tax Instead of Law May Affect Environmental Policy


Macdonald, Doug, Alternatives Journal


IN THE SPRING OF 1992 the Ontario government made two contrary decisions. It refused to implement its own Fair Tax Commission's recommendation for an increase in the "gas guzzler

tax" to promote motor vehicle fuel efficiency, but it did impose a "beer can levy" with the stated purpose of giving consumers an incentive to purchase beer in reusable alcohol containers. Environmentalists, who now increasingly call for greater use of the economic instrument of green taxation,(1) might well wonder why Ontario was willing to impose a green tax in one case but not in the other.

On both issues, the government was subject to strong lobbying pressures from industry, labour and environmentalists. Motor vehicle manufacturers and elements of labour opposed the gas guzzler tax, while in the case of the non-refillable container tax, industry was split -- the domestic brewers were in support and can manufacturers (and labour) in opposition. These differences in lobbying pressures help to explain the contradictory policy outcomes. But there is another factor, which to date, has been largely ignored in green taxation deliberations.

Choosing to use a tax instead of relying on the usual regulatory approach changes policy making by bringing a new actor into the community of participants.2 When tax is used as an environmental policy instrument, finance department officials gain a larger role relative to their environment department colleagues than is the case when standard regulations are used. This change in the policy community is likely to affect both the character and the potential effectiveness of the resulting action.

The "policy communities" approach to analysis of public sector decision making recognizes that governments do not develop policy by simply following a rational, technical process of identifying a problem, setting objectives and then selecting an instrument such as law or tax to achieve those objectives. Policy makers are also influenced by the various pressures brought to bear by interested groups. Governments are not, however, completely in the thrall of such groups. In environmental policy making, state actors such as the Ontario Ministry of Environment and Energy have at least some autonomy. But they develop policy through a dynamic of interaction both with other state actors (within their own government and at the federal and municipal level) and with nonstate actors such as business interests and environmental groups, all of whom possess sufficient technical expertise to engage in the relevant policy discussion. Together they constitute the policy community", which within the broad parameters of general societal objectives such as wealth creation and human rights, negotiate policy positions and determine how the policies will be applied.

Accordingly, the policy process is influenced more than anything else by the political strength of the relevant state and non-state actors. The regulated industry is by far the most significant non-state actor. Since they may be asked to change behaviour and internalize cost, business firms have a powerful incentive to attempt to influence environmental policy makers. Typically, the firm is motivated primarily by a desire to maximize profit by expanding the potential market and maximizing market share and by minimizing costs, both through internal efficiencies and through externalization of costs.

Despite their rhetoric, firms in the environmental policy field generally prefer command regulation (or its latest variant -- voluntary agreements) over economic instruments. Judith Rees, arguing that firms can evade command regulations more easily than taxes, has put the case clearly:

It is interesting to note that the industrial lobby, so convinced

of the value of market mechanisms and freedom

from government interference, has been implacable in its

opposition to environmental quality markets, preferring

direct regulation!

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
Loading One moment ...
Project items
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

Cited article

Beer Cans, Gas Guzzlers and Green Taxes: How Using Tax Instead of Law May Affect Environmental Policy
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

While we understand printed pages are helpful to our users, this limitation is necessary to help protect our publishers' copyrighted material and prevent its unlawful distribution. We are sorry for any inconvenience.
Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

Cited passage

Welcome to the new Questia Reader

The Questia Reader has been updated to provide you with an even better online reading experience.  It is now 100% Responsive, which means you can read our books and articles on any sized device you wish.  All of your favorite tools like notes, highlights, and citations are still here, but the way you select text has been updated to be easier to use, especially on touchscreen devices.  Here's how:

1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
2. Click or tap the last word you want to select.

OK, got it!

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.

Are you sure you want to delete this highlight?