Natural Law and Modern Economic Theory

By Moreno-Riano, Gerson | Journal of Markets & Morality, Fall 2005 | Go to article overview

Natural Law and Modern Economic Theory


Moreno-Riano, Gerson, Journal of Markets & Morality


The concept of natural law is pervasive in academic discussions of ethics, politics, and jurisprudence. However, it is much more difficult to unearth the influence of and relationship between natural law and modern economic theory within current scholarly dialogue. This unfortunate lacuna in scholarship is inter alia due to the facts that natural law suffers from an inherent ambiguity as to whether its foundations are religious and it lacks any rigorous scientific validation. This article defends and advances the importance of natural law for modern economic theory. In doing so, it presents the classical view of natural law as found in the work of Thomas Aquinas and addresses both its religious foundations as well as scientific evidence for its existence. Beyond offering a portrait and defense of natural law, this article discusses the specific contributions that natural law offers to modern economic theory in an attempt to imbue the latter with a more complete notion of humanity and existence.

**********

The popularity of the concept of natural law cannot be doubted. It is used by both scholars and nonacademics of all genres in a wide variety of contexts and discussions. Beyond its contemporary use (or misuse!), natural law--the claim that universal and nonconventional dictates of right and wrong exist within nature (1)--has enjoyed a long and distinguished history. In the Western intellectual tradition, (2) the centrality of natural law as a ground for morals and politics captivated the ancient Greek and Roman intellectuals and continued to influence politico-juridical discussions throughout the medieval, modern, and contemporary eras. While the pervasive influence of natural law to discussions of ethics, politics, and jurisprudence is well documented, (3) it is much more difficult to unearth the influence of and relationship between natural law and modern economic theory within current scholarship. (4)

The paucity of scholarship regarding the relationship between natural law and economic theory in current scholarship may be due to several factors. Within intellectual history, natural law has been primarily advanced within theories of ethics, political obligation, and jurisprudence. (5) Few have therefore developed or investigated a connection between natural-law premises and economic theory. (6) Further, there is an inherent ambiguity within natural law as to whether its foundations are religious. (7) As such, advocates of modern economic theory, insofar as this theory is nonreligious, would suggest that there is little of use in a natural-law framework that, in their view, is primarily faith based and therefore nonscientific. Lastly, natural law suffers from a lack of attempts at empirical validation, leaving it as the substance of academic debate and historical investigation but of little social, political, and economic value. (8)

This current state of affairs is unfortunate and unnecessary. Neither the lack of investigation into the link between natural law and economic theory nor the prevalence or lack thereof of its religious foundations necessarily deny any fruitful connection between natural law and modern economic theory. As Morse (1998) has argued, modern economic theory and natural law share several areas of common ground that would allow "natural-law thinking" to make a "significant point of entry into dialogue with modern economics." (9) Even more pointed is Piedra's argument for the subordination of economics to the moral norms of natural law:

   It is true that the formal object of economics is concerned with
   the dynamics of change and the production of goods and services.
   But economics, being a social science, is also concerned with the
   knowledge of means and results in relation to a desired goal. If
   the economic process rests on free actions of men which are not
   "naturally" determined, then ... economic science cannot renounce
   the prerogative of being a practical science oriented by a
   scientifically established and founded norm, and to this extent of
   being normative. 

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Natural Law and Modern Economic Theory
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Welcome to the new Questia Reader

The Questia Reader has been updated to provide you with an even better online reading experience.  It is now 100% Responsive, which means you can read our books and articles on any sized device you wish.  All of your favorite tools like notes, highlights, and citations are still here, but the way you select text has been updated to be easier to use, especially on touchscreen devices.  Here's how:

1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
2. Click or tap the last word you want to select.

OK, got it!

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.