Demand Response to Cost Sharing under Managed Health Care

By Lu, Chunling; Frank, Richard G. et al. | Contemporary Economic Policy, January 2009 | Go to article overview

Demand Response to Cost Sharing under Managed Health Care


Lu, Chunling, Frank, Richard G., McGuire, Thomas G., Contemporary Economic Policy


I. INTRODUCTION

Demand response is one of the most venerable topics in health economics. Zeckhauser (1970) related demand response to optimal (second-best) health insurance showing that a greater demand response implied less coverage. That is, when cost-sharing provisions are the only instruments for controlling use of care, control of moral hazard requires reduced coverage. Zeckhauser's work set out the theoretical foundation for the largest economics research project of the 1970s and 1980s, the RAND Health Insurance Experiment (New-house and the Insurance Experiment Group, 1993). With the ascendance of managed care in 1990s, empirical research on demand response declined. This was due in part to great reliance on provider payment incentives and administrative processes to control use of health care. In this way, controlling costs could be done without shifting financial risk to consumers, seemingly rendering demand side cost sharing--the portion of the bill the patient pays--obsolete.

Ma and McGuire (1997) generalized Zeckhauser's model to both supply-side cost sharing which imposes financial penalties on doctors for using referred services and demand-side cost sharing, demonstrating the superiority of supply-side instruments for controlling quantity while allowing for expansion of insurance coverage to protect against risk. In line with this idea, consumers' out-of-pocket burden for health-care cost fell in real terms during the 1990s and fell greatly in relation to total health-care costs. According to Health United States published by National Center for Health Statistics (2003), in 1990, the inflation adjusted (year 2000 dollars) personal out-of-pocket expenditures were $224.1 billion. By 2000, they had decreased to $194.1 billion. Out-of-pocket expenditures declined as a percent of total personal health-care expenditures from 22.5% in 1990 to 17.1% in 2000. Since the mid-1990s, the percentage of workers enrolled in some kind of managed care plans (MC) has increased from 77% in 1996 to 93% in 2006 (The Kaiser Family Foundation and Health Research and Education Trust 1998, 2006).

Coincident with this growth in managed care enrollment was the so-called "backlash" against managed care's rationing methods. Providers resented being told what services were appropriate and patients disliked the bureaucracy of seeking permission from specific types of care. The negative reaction to restricted choice of provider and stringent approval processes manifests in the market and through the political process. Private and public policy makers have loosened administrative controls of health-care utilization and are returning to reliance on demand-side cost sharing to ration health-care services. Nevertheless, these cost-sharing arrangements are being implemented in the context of a health-care delivery system that still relies heavily on payments arrangements that reward provider for doing less administrative mechanisms and capacity constraints to ration care. In considering policies such as high-deductible health plans that aim to use demand prices to ration services, it once again becomes important to understand demand response. However, because the basic institutions that insure and pay for health care have changed since the 1980s, new research is necessary to quantify the magnitude of demand response within managed health-care plans (Health Maintenance Organizations [HMOs], Preferred Provider Organizations [PPOs], and Point of Service plans).

Expectations about the ability of new forms of cost-sharing arrangements to save money and steer care toward more efficient types of care depends critically on demand response. The Congressional Budget Office and some actuaries continue to rely on the results of the RAND Health Insurance Experiment to project response to high-deductible health plans or to various cost-sharing arrangements. This article seeks to provide estimates of demand response to cost-sharing arrangements within the context of recent institutions that pay for and manage health care for the vast majority (93%) of privately insured Americans (Employer Health Benefits 2006).

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Demand Response to Cost Sharing under Managed Health Care
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Welcome to the new Questia Reader

The Questia Reader has been updated to provide you with an even better online reading experience.  It is now 100% Responsive, which means you can read our books and articles on any sized device you wish.  All of your favorite tools like notes, highlights, and citations are still here, but the way you select text has been updated to be easier to use, especially on touchscreen devices.  Here's how:

1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
2. Click or tap the last word you want to select.

OK, got it!

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.