Effect of Multi-Fiber Arrangement Trade Restrictions on Textile Industry Profit Margins

By Xu, Peng | Contemporary Economic Policy, July 1997 | Go to article overview

Effect of Multi-Fiber Arrangement Trade Restrictions on Textile Industry Profit Margins


Xu, Peng, Contemporary Economic Policy


I. INTRODUCTION

Since the 1960s, world trade in textiles and apparel has been subject to an increasing array of bilateral quota arrangements. The range of products subject to restraints expanded from mostly cotton textiles under the early quota arrangements in the 1960s and early 1970s to an ever increasing list of natural and manmade fibers under four iterations of the Multi-Fiber Arrangement (MFA) beginning in 1974.

In the United States, the textile and apparel industries receive higher levels of protection than does any other manufacturing sector. The estimated tariff rate equivalent of all U.S. protection (tariffs and quotas combined) is 23.4% of textiles, and 48% of apparel (Schott, 1994). Restraints under the MFA and earlier quota arrangements may have provided a certain degree of market certainty and, consequently, a stable environment that allowed U.S. manufacturers to undertake major technological changes. However, by limiting import competition, the MFA trade restraints may have enabled U.S. manufacturers to enjoy higher market power and profit margins (Pelzman, 1984). Consequently, they cost U.S. consumers billions of dollars in terms of welfare loss. Hufbauer and Elliott (1994) estimate that total elimination of import quotas would provide more than $15 billion welfare gain to U.S. consumers.

Theoretical literature on the role and effect of trade policy in imperfectly competitive markets is well-established. Helpman and Krugman (1989) offer a synthesis of the "new" theory of trade policy arising specifically from the presence of imperfect competition. On the other hand, much empirical trade literature assumes perfect competition for the market under investigation. In trade policy analysis, imperfect competition and market power can lead to non-standard policy effects. Therefore, empirical analysis of trade policy should be based on a modeling approach that allows for imperfect competition and market power.

Recently, trade economists have begun to apply methods of the "new empirical industrial organization," which advocates applying time series data from single industries or from closely related industries to trade policy studies. Levinsohn (1993), for instance, uses a method of the new empirical industrial organization to investigate the pro-competitive effect of trade liberalization policy in the Turkish manufacturing sector in 1984 and finds that reducing import barriers depressed domestic price-cost margins.

This article tests the hypothesis that MFA trade restrictions, by limiting import competition, promoted domestic non-competitive behavior and raised domestic profit margins. The empirical analysis also is conducted in the spirit of the new empirical industrial organization. For the selected sub-sectors of the textile industry, the results show significant evidence of the anti-competitive effect of trade restrictions. Protection under the MFA has enabled U.S. producers to raise their profit margins and has reduced domestic welfare due to increased domestic market power.

II. HISTORICAL BACKGROUND

In the 1950s, the U.S. textile industry experienced market adjustment problems caused by the shift to man-made fibers, technological changes, and intensifying import competition from Japan. To partially alleviate these problems and to be able to undertake technological adjustments with the least market disruptions caused by import competition, the U.S. textile industry sought protection from import competition primarily from Japan. The administration, pursuant to the authority granted under the Agricultural Act of 1956, negotiated a five-year voluntary restraint agreement on cotton textile exports from Japan for the period 195761. (The information here and throughout this section comes from The U.S. International Trade Commission's various publications.)

Because of their discriminatory nature, the voluntary export restraints curtailed imports only from Japan while encouraging imports from smaller unrestrained exporting countries. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Effect of Multi-Fiber Arrangement Trade Restrictions on Textile Industry Profit Margins
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Welcome to the new Questia Reader

The Questia Reader has been updated to provide you with an even better online reading experience.  It is now 100% Responsive, which means you can read our books and articles on any sized device you wish.  All of your favorite tools like notes, highlights, and citations are still here, but the way you select text has been updated to be easier to use, especially on touchscreen devices.  Here's how:

1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
2. Click or tap the last word you want to select.

OK, got it!

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.