The Aggregate Demand/supply Model: A Premature Requiem?

By Truett, Lila J.; Truett, Dale B. | American Economist, Spring 1998 | Go to article overview

The Aggregate Demand/supply Model: A Premature Requiem?


Truett, Lila J., Truett, Dale B., American Economist


Two recent articles [Barro (1994) and Geithman (1994)] have argued that the aggregate demand/aggregate supply approach is incorrect and/or inappropriate for explaining macroeconomic theory (or theories) to students. The purpose of this brief note is not to criticize the positions of Barro and Geithman; in fact, we believe both authors make some valid points. However, we argue that while its underpinnings are somewhat complex, a carefully defined aggregate demand/aggregate supply model may in fact be quite useful in illustrating the critical differences and commonalities among various theoretical explanations of how the macroeconomy works.(1)

Definitions of Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply

It appears that some of the confusion regarding aggregate demand and supply models has arisen because different writers have defined aggregate demand and aggregate supply differently. We shall present definitions of aggregate demand (AD) and aggregate supply (AS) that are different from some of those in the literature, but which we believe are most useful to illustrate a number of fundamental issues in macroeconomics. In this context, aggregate demand is the relationship between the real quantity demanded of newly produced final goods and services in an economy and the general price level, under the constraint that if the aggregate quantity supplied were equal to the quantity depicted on the horizontal axis, the aggregate quantity demanded would be equal to it.(2) With this definition, the aggregate demand curve is a set of coordinate points (aggregate quantity demanded, aggregate price level) that represent equilibrium points in the Keynesian demand model. Thus, the AD curve is actually an aggregate demand-side equilibrium curve.

With this definition of aggregate demand and following where others have tread, we must turn to reasons other than the income and substitution effects used to justify the slope of the demand curve for a single product. On an aggregate basis, if all prices in the economy rise proportionally, money incomes will also, and therefore there is no reason for the traditional income and substitution effects found in an individual product market. Thus, the downward slope of the aggregate demand curve has usually been justified by the real balances effect (the Pigou effect) and the interest rate effect (the Keynes effect).(4) The former effect occurs because a decrease in the general price level increases the real wealth of those holding financial assets. Of course, the real wealth of debtors is correspondingly decreased, but traditionally it has been argued that the government, a net debtor, is not affected by such declines in wealth. It is argued that the interest rate effect occurs because as prices fall, the quantity supplied of money in real terms exceeds the quantity demanded. As a result, actions are taken in the financial markets that cause interest rates to fall. Correspondingly, the quantity demanded of consumption goods and investment goods rises.

We turn now to aggregate supply, which we define as the relationship between the real quantity supplied of newly produced final goods and services in an economy and the general price level. Underpinning this definition of aggregate supply is the assumption that relative input costs and output prices are adjusted so that there is no excess quantity demanded or excess quantity supplied of any factor of production at any point on the aggregate supply curve. Although the aggregate supply curve has been defined in a variety of ways, the above definition, where the aggregate supply curve represents equilibria in the input markets, appears most useful in illustrating the differences in the various explanations of the macroeconomy.(5) Thus, it is really an aggregate supply-side equilibrium or a factor market equilibrium curve.

Some economists draw this (so called, long-run) aggregate supply curve as a vertical line, indicating the maximum quantity of goods and services that an economy could produce. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

The Aggregate Demand/supply Model: A Premature Requiem?
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Welcome to the new Questia Reader

The Questia Reader has been updated to provide you with an even better online reading experience.  It is now 100% Responsive, which means you can read our books and articles on any sized device you wish.  All of your favorite tools like notes, highlights, and citations are still here, but the way you select text has been updated to be easier to use, especially on touchscreen devices.  Here's how:

1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
2. Click or tap the last word you want to select.

OK, got it!

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.