Financial Crises, Sound Policies and Sound Institutions: An Interview with Michael Bordo

By Singleton, John | The Reserve Bank of New Zealand Bulletin, September 2009 | Go to article overview

Financial Crises, Sound Policies and Sound Institutions: An Interview with Michael Bordo


Singleton, John, The Reserve Bank of New Zealand Bulletin


How did you come to do advanced studies in economics and to focus your research on financial crises?

I started my university education at McGill University in Montreal. I was always interested in history and political science and I developed an interest in economics. In a course in my first year at McGill, Frank Cyril James gave a spectacular course on global economic history, with the culmination of the course being the 1931 Financial Crisis. I just loved this course, and eventually took Honours [in] economics and political science at McGill. The teachers we had were excellent. I knew I wanted to go to graduate school, I knew I wanted to be a professor. I decided to apply to the London School of Economics, and not really knowing what I was going to do, I signed up for public finance. I later switched to advanced economic theory. Being in the Masters programme at LSE was a very enjoyable time for me. There, I met Bill Phillips.

When you went to the LSE, were you aware that Phillips was an important character and that he'd done very important research?

Yes, but not that much--I was still green in the profession. I was impressed with Lionel Robbins and gave a paper in his seminar. That was really a very exciting event for me. There were other great people at LSE and Phillips was one of them, but he wasn't really on my radar screen. I knew about the Phillips Curve, but it's not something that was dominating our thinking. We were being taught very Keynesian-type macro, as anybody who went to university in England or Canada at the time was getting.

[ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]

Was Phillips himself a Keynesian?

Well, I'm giving you my impressions as a graduate student at 21 years old. He gave a series of lectures and demonstrated how his machine could explain the circular flow of income in a very simple Keynesian model. He had a concept of the economy as a control system, in today's sense. You know, a control system whereby the central bank and the treasury together would push policy levers and regulate the circular flow of income, offsetting negative injections with positive injections. His model was a Keynesian model, so that's what I mean when I say he was a Keynesian--he had a very simple Keynesian framework.

He also talked about the Phillips Curve, but it wasn't called the Phillips Curve then. He discussed the empirical relationship he found between the rate of change in money wages and the level of unemployment in Great Britain from 1857 to 1951. He fitted the line through it and then discussed how it was hard to interpret--he did not give us a theory. We got the theory from Richard Lipsey. Lipsey had the story of how the Phillips Curve was picking up excess demand in a very simple Keynesian-cross type of model, but Phillips didn't talk about that.

Was Phillips a good lecturer?

He was very nice, charming, modest, funny--he had this really strong New Zealand accent.

After the LSE, you went to Chicago to do your PhD and ended up with Milton Friedman as your supervisor. Why did you choose Chicago?

I got interested in Chicago from talking to my instructors at LSE, especially Ed Mishan, who was my advisor in the second year. He had done his PhD at Chicago and was a student of Milton Friedman. He wrote a strong letter for me and Harry Johnson arranged everything for me. Mishan just wrote a letter on one of those old-fashioned blue aerograms and shipped it off to Harry and, bang, I got in with a full scholarship.

The thing about Chicago was that I was always fascinated by the Chicago School and Friedman and Stigler. At LSE they were really anti-Friedman, and I sort of went along with it, but I was always curious. I wanted to find out what the Chicago School was all about, and when I got there I was assigned Milton Friedman as my advisor. He was extremely nice to me and said, 'You were at LSE, you've had a British education and studied in Canada--you've got a lot of advantage over the other students from the United States--and I'm really happy that you could be with me'.

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Financial Crises, Sound Policies and Sound Institutions: An Interview with Michael Bordo
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Welcome to the new Questia Reader

The Questia Reader has been updated to provide you with an even better online reading experience.  It is now 100% Responsive, which means you can read our books and articles on any sized device you wish.  All of your favorite tools like notes, highlights, and citations are still here, but the way you select text has been updated to be easier to use, especially on touchscreen devices.  Here's how:

1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
2. Click or tap the last word you want to select.

OK, got it!

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.