The Peopling of Macroeconomics: Microeconomics of Aggregate Consumer Expenditures

By Chatterjee, Satyajit | Business Review (Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia), Spring 2009 | Go to article overview
Save to active project

The Peopling of Macroeconomics: Microeconomics of Aggregate Consumer Expenditures


Chatterjee, Satyajit, Business Review (Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia)


Consumer spending is the largest single expenditure category in the final demand for goods and services, accounting for more than two-thirds of gross domestic product (GDP). A clear understanding of the underpinnings of consumer spending is a valuable asset for central bankers and policymakers. Since the 1950s, macroeconomists have been engaged in building a theory of aggregate consumer spending from the bottom up. (1) In this approach, macroeconomists first seek to understand how individual households choose to spend and how their choices change when interest rates, the unemployment rate, and other indicators of overall economic activity change. The relationship between aggregate consumer spending and indicators of economic activity is then obtained by aggregating the predicted changes in the spending choices of individual households with respect to changes in indicators of overall economic activity.

It was not always so. In the early years of macroeconomics, scholars looked for enduring empirical relationships ("economic laws") that connected one set of macroeconomic aggregates to another without explicit reference to the individual decisions that would make sense of such connections. This was because economists hadn't fully worked out how a household acting rationally in the face of uncertainty would behave over time--the sort of knowledge needed to meaningfully connect macroeconomic aggregates to the millions of individual choices that make up those aggregates. But as economists began to acquire this knowledge, the process of connecting macroeconomics to individuals' behavior started in the 1950s and gathered steam in the 1970s and 1980s. Although the process of integration is far from complete, predictions of aggregate consumer spending are now rooted in predictions of individual behavior.

The attempt to predict aggregate consumer spending by first predicting what individual households would do is what I mean by "the peopling of macroeconomics." The aim of this article is to give an account of this now half-century-long intellectual endeavor. It is meant to be a (quick!) historical survey that takes the reader from the early work on the consumption function to the theory of aggregate consumer spending in modern macroeconomic models.

GENESIS OF THE CONSUMPTION FUNCTION

The origin of macroeconomics as a distinct sub-field of economics is often traced to John Maynard Keynes's General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money. Published in 1936, the book sought to explain the reasons for the economic depression that gripped the industrialized world after 1929. In the course of doing so, Keynes introduced a theoretical construct he called the consumption function. According to Keynes, the consumption function was the causal relationship between annual aggregate disposable (or after-tax) income and annual aggregate consumer spending.

Keynes asserted that this relationship looked like the brown line shown in Figure 1. Aggregate consumer spending was directly and linearly related to aggregate disposable income. The point at which the brown line crosses the black line gives the income level at which consumer

spending is equal to income. To the left of this point, spending exceeds income, and to the right of this point, spending is less than income. Importantly, the relationship between income and spending was a nonproportional one, with higher incomes associated with a smaller ratio of spending to income. To see this, consider the points marked X and Y on the brown line. At point X income is $40,000 and spending is $34,000; at point Y, income is $80,000 and spending is $58,000. Thus, a doubling of income leads to less than a doubling of spending, which means that the ratio of spending to income declines as incomes rise.

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

Because the consumption function was central to Keynes's analysis, the construct attracted a great deal of attention and soon became the focus of controversy.

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
Loading One moment ...
Project items
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

Cited article

The Peopling of Macroeconomics: Microeconomics of Aggregate Consumer Expenditures
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

While we understand printed pages are helpful to our users, this limitation is necessary to help protect our publishers' copyrighted material and prevent its unlawful distribution. We are sorry for any inconvenience.
Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

Cited passage

Welcome to the new Questia Reader

The Questia Reader has been updated to provide you with an even better online reading experience.  It is now 100% Responsive, which means you can read our books and articles on any sized device you wish.  All of your favorite tools like notes, highlights, and citations are still here, but the way you select text has been updated to be easier to use, especially on touchscreen devices.  Here's how:

1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
2. Click or tap the last word you want to select.

OK, got it!

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.

Are you sure you want to delete this highlight?