Smith versus Keynes: Economics and Political Economy in the Post-Crisis Era

By Gregg, Samuel | Harvard Journal of Law & Public Policy, Spring 2010 | Go to article overview

Smith versus Keynes: Economics and Political Economy in the Post-Crisis Era


Gregg, Samuel, Harvard Journal of Law & Public Policy


INTRODUCTION

Alongside politicians, bankers, and CEOs, few groups have received as much opprobrium for the 2008 financial crisis as economists. "Economists are the forgotten guilty men" was the phrase employed in February 2009 by Anatole Kaletsky, editor-at-large for the London Times, when explaining why "a bank with just $1 billion of capital [would] borrow an extra $99 billion and then buy $100 billion of speculative investments." (1) Self-indulgence and imprudence had a part, but so too, Kaletsky asserted, did those economists who insisted that their models "proved" that occurrences such as Long Term Capital Management's demise in 1998 or Lehman Brothers's collapse almost exactly ten years later were mathematically likely to happen only once every billion years. (2) Kaletsky's wider claim was that mainstream economics had been so discredited by the financial crisis that economics itself required an "intellectual revolution" or risked being reduced to a somewhat suspect sub-branch of mathematical modeling and statistical analysis.

Kaletsky has not been alone in making such arguments. Economic historian Harold James made a similar point, albeit more temperately:

   [A]n overwhelming majority of modern economists were misled by
   treating short-term trends as if they were permanent phenomena that
   could be used to derive reliable behavioral correlations and
   extrapolations. There were some exceptions ... but such analysts
   were dismissed as alarmist or eccentric, not only by the
   commercially driven economists who worked for financial
   institutions as de facto salesmen, but also by the overwhelming
   majority of academic economists, who were also subject to
   commercial pressures in the forms of peer evaluation and patterns
   of career development. These economists instilled a false
   complacency in politicians and other policymakers. (3)

In March 2009, Willem Butler, a former external member of the Bank of England's Monetary Policy Committee, likewise referred to "[t]he unfortunate uselessness of most 'state of the art' academic monetary economics." (4) Though unwilling to demand either a complete paradigm change or a defenestration of the economics profession, the Economist suggested that the financial meltdown raised profound questions of coherence about two specific fields of economics: financial economics and macroeconomics. "Few financial economists," it suggested, "thought much about illiquidity or counterparty risk, for instance, because their standard models ignore it." Likewise, "[m]acroeconomists also had a blind spot: their standard models assumed that capital markets work perfectly." (5)

These claims evoked a strong riposte from the Nobel Prize economist Robert Lucas in defense of the Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH), the claim that the price of a financial asset reflects all relevant, generally available information. "One thing," Lucas wrote, "we are not going to have, now or ever, is a set of models that forecasts sudden falls in the value of financial assets, like the declines that followed the failure of Lehman Brothers in September [2008]." (6) Since the late Paul Samuelson published his proof for one version of the EMH in 1965 and Eugene Fama detailed the theory and evidence for three forms of the EMH in 1970, (7) the EMH had been subject to consistent criticism. But none of these critiques, Lucas maintained, had proved its falsity. Other economists, however, argued that the stock market meltdown demonstrated the EMH's inability to account for the market overpricing assets such as mortgages. On this basis, they conjectured, "the EMH, as applied to the stock market in aggregate, must be discarded or modified." (8)

While these discussions are important, much of the debate about economic theory following the 2008 crisis has focused upon the place of models in economics. Some contemporary economists seem hesitant to question the appropriateness of their heavy dependence on models and mathematical logic. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Smith versus Keynes: Economics and Political Economy in the Post-Crisis Era
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.