You Do Have to Keep Your Promises: A Disgorgement Theory of Contract Remedies

By Thel, Steve; Siegelman, Peter | William and Mary Law Review, March 2011 | Go to article overview

You Do Have to Keep Your Promises: A Disgorgement Theory of Contract Remedies


Thel, Steve, Siegelman, Peter, William and Mary Law Review


ABSTRACT

Contract law is generally understood to require no more of a person who breaches a contract than to give the injured promisee the "benefit of the bargain." The law is thus assumed to permit a promise-breaker to keep any profit remaining from breach, after putting the victim in the position he would have been in had the promise been performed. This conventional description is radically wrong: across a wide range of circumstances, standard contract doctrines actually do require people to keep their promises, or to disgorge their entire profit from breach if they do not. Rather than protecting the expectation interest of injured promisees, therefore, the law of contract remedies is better characterized as enforcing "promisor expectation" or disgorgement, a regime that puts breaching promisors in the position they would have been in had they performed, even when that means overcompensating injured victims.

We offer two explanations for why we so often see "promisor expectation" remedies, even though contracting parties would prefer the remedy of perfect promisee expectation damages. First, promisor expectation is often much easier for courts to compute or implement than promisee-based remedies. Second, promisors themselves prefer to be subject to the promisor expectation regime because it allows them to commit credibly to perform their promises. Such commitments are valuable but cannot be sustained if the law awards damages that fall short of perfect promisee expectation, as it invariably does. By agreeing to a remedial scheme that makes it unprofitable or impossible for them to profit from breach, promisors can credibly commit to perform and thus realize a higher contract price ex ante. An "overcompensatory" remedy thus paradoxically serves the interests of promisors by providing them a valuable bonding mechanism.

TABLE OF CONTENTS

INTRODUCTION

I. THE ARGUMENT
   A. The Conventional Wisdom
   B. Prior Scholarship on Disgorgement .
II. THE AVAILABILITY OF PROMISOR EXPECTATION REMEDIES IN CONTRACT LAW
   A. What's a Widget?--The Continuity of Promisor Expectation Remedies
      1. Hypothetical Cover--Promisor Expectation
         When the Price of Performance Is Clear
      2. Specific Performance--Promisor Expectation
         When the Price of Performance Is Not Clear
         a. The Ordinary Remedy
         b. Ancillary Equitable Remedies
         c. Negative Injunctions
         d. Efficient Breach
      3. The Inadequacy Test Promisor Expectation in Between
   B. Promisor Expectation Elsewhere in Contract Law
      1. The Exclusive Benefit Rule
      2. Promisor Expectation by Characterization
      3. Promisor Expectation Through Rescission
   C. Innocent Breach--When Promisors Can Keep the
      Expenses They Avoid by Breach
III. EXPLAINING PROMISOR EXPECTATION
   A. Promisor Expectation as a Simple Remedy
   B. Promisor Expectation as a Promisor
      Bonding Mechanism
      1. The Example of Fiduciary Duties
      2. Bonding in Ordinary Contractual Settings
CONCLUSION
APPENDIX: A COMPARISON OF UNDERCOMPENSATORY- EXPECTATION
          AND DISGORGEMENT RULES

INTRODUCTION

"The only universal consequence of a legally binding promise is, that the law makes the promisor pay damages if the promised event does not come to pass. In every case it leaves him free from interference until the time for fulfillment has gone by, and therefore free to break his contract if he chooses."

--O.W. Holmes, Jr., The Common Law, 301 (1881)

"It is no reason for not enforcing a contract that the defendant can make ... more money by avoiding his agreement than by carrying it out."

--Roberts v. City of Cambridge, 49 N.E. 84, 84 (Mass. 1898)

Suppose that Jack promises Jill to deliver a pail of water in one week for a price of $10, payable on delivery. Jill values the pail of water at $12. Before the time for delivery arrives, though, Mr. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

You Do Have to Keep Your Promises: A Disgorgement Theory of Contract Remedies
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.