Valuing Pollution: Problems of Price in the Commodification of Nature

By Paton, Joy; Bryant, Gareth | The Economic and Labour Relations Review : ELRR, February 2012 | Go to article overview

Valuing Pollution: Problems of Price in the Commodification of Nature


Paton, Joy, Bryant, Gareth, The Economic and Labour Relations Review : ELRR


Introduction

Extending the sphere of the market as a mechanism for environmental policy was enthusiastically embraced by governments during the 1990s following the Brundtland Commission's (WCED 1987) promotion of 'sustainable development'. The conflation of 'sustainability' (the ecological problem) with 'development' (the economic problem) was a key factor in laying the foundation for economic norms in environmental policy and management to the neglect of preserving ecological integrity. After two decades of national and international policies for sustainable development, global environmental degradation continues and a new wave of concern has emerged (Kovel 2002: 4; UNEP 2007). The recent Reviews by Stern (2006) and Garnaut (2011) sought to tackle climbing global emissions of carbon dioxide (Worldwatch Institute 2002: 5), but have ensured that any debate about the use of market instruments neglects the question of their suitability in this circumstance. Rather, debate is confined to the problem of how best to implement such instruments (Paton 2008: 107). This was evident in the establishment of the Australian Multi-Party Climate Change Committee, convened to investigate ways of 'pricing' carbon and resulting in the negotiation of the 'Clean Energy Future' emissions trading scheme.

The United Nations Conference on Environment and Development (UNCED 1992) institutionalised the role of market instruments in climate change policies through the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC). Economic approaches, central to UNFCCC, gained practical momentum with the Kyoto Protocol in 1997. The only global agreement to mandate quantitative greenhouse gas (GHG) emission limits for developed economies of the North, it institutes economic instruments as the means for achieving targets. The Protocol embodies three 'flexible mechanisms' which pivot on the creation of emissions trading schemes and the pricing of GHG emissions. A new commodity in the form of 'emissions reductions' (or removals) is the basis for a process whereby GHGs (primarily carbon dioxide) are monitored, priced and traded in a 'carbon market' (UNFCCC 2010). Of the three Kyoto mechanisms, the Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) represents the most extensive carbon trading instrument in terms of the volume of economic activity it has generated and its spatial reach between global North and South.

The CDM is a baseline-and-credit carbon offsetting instrument which allows for the development of carbon pollution 'reducing' projects in Southern countries. Common project types include hydropower dam and biomass waste renewable energy projects, industrial gas destruction factories, carbon sequestration from tree plantations and energy efficiency installations. Projects produce carbon credits, known as Certified Emission Reductions (CERs). These are traded on financial markets and finally surrendered by governments and businesses in Northern countries in order to meet their carbon emission reduction requirements. CER credits commodify the capacity of the climate system to absorb and cycle one tonne of carbon dioxide-equivalent because they are used by companies and governments in the North to 'offset' their real GHG pollution. Significantly, the Kyoto Protocol states that in addressing climate change through the production of such credits, the CDM will also 'contribute' to sustainable development in the South (UNFCCC 1997: 11). The inclusion of this second goal demonstrates the perceived congruence between economic instruments and sustainable development, particularly as a means to resolve North-South tensions in global environmental politics. (1)

However, it is far from self-evident that economic theories provide an appropriate basis for managing the environmental commons or for meeting the normative challenges of sustainability, climate change being the ultimate test of both. The unavoidably collective and interdisciplinary character of ecological problems makes suspect their amenability to the atomistic theory and method of free market economics. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Valuing Pollution: Problems of Price in the Commodification of Nature
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Welcome to the new Questia Reader

The Questia Reader has been updated to provide you with an even better online reading experience.  It is now 100% Responsive, which means you can read our books and articles on any sized device you wish.  All of your favorite tools like notes, highlights, and citations are still here, but the way you select text has been updated to be easier to use, especially on touchscreen devices.  Here's how:

1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
2. Click or tap the last word you want to select.

OK, got it!

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.