Keynes after the Crisis

By Backhouse, Roger E.; Bateman, Bradley W. | Renewal, Autumn-Winter 2011 | Go to article overview

Keynes after the Crisis


Backhouse, Roger E., Bateman, Bradley W., Renewal


The short-lived rediscovery of Keynes

In 2008, the world rediscovered John Maynard Keynes as it faced the possibility that there would be a collapse of the banking system leading to another Great Depression.

However, despite the anger that was widely felt towards the bankers and financiers who had created this situation, the crisis was not accompanied by significant financial reform, while the monetary expansion that the government undertook in response to the crisis failed to stimulate investment in the way that had been hoped: the newly created cash was used to reinforce the balance sheets of both the banks and other large corporations, but there was virtually none of the investment in plant and equipment that creates new jobs. Governments ended up acquiring debts that were perceived to be unsustainable, dictating that governments turn their budget deficits into surpluses.

The end result was therefore a reversion to the orthodoxy that Keynes had attacked, according to which recovery depended on cutting public spending, since raising taxation, especially on high incomes, was considered a non-starter. There is much here that still needs to be understood - the way calls for financial reform were stifled and the way it was assumed that cutting deficits meant cutting spending rather than raising existing taxes or designing new ones almost cries out for 'public choice' analysis - but what is clear is that the crisis ended up becoming yet another cue for an assault on the welfare state (1).

Part of the reason, as Tony Judt suggested, is that we are no longer able to imagine a social democratic future:

  Why do we experience such difficulty in even imagining a different
  sort of society? Why is it beyond us to conceive a different set of
  arrangements to our common advantage? Are we doomed
  indefinitely to lurch between a dysfunctional 'free market' and the
  much-advertised horrors of 'socialism'? Our difficulty is discursive:
  we simply do not know how to talk about these things any more.
  (Judt, 2010, 34)

We no longer have the language in which to justify the type of economy that, from the 1940s to the 1970s, underwrote an increasingly more equal society. Or, to adopt the analysis of the American historian Daniel Rodgers, we have allowed our understanding of the social to become so fractured, or hollowed out, as to be unable to support any convincing alternative to 'free market' economics based on assumptions of rational choice:

  Across the multiple fronts of ideational battle, from the speeches of
  presidents to books of social and cultural theory, conceptions of
  human nature that in the post-World War II era had been thick with
  context, social circumstance, institutions, and
  history gave way to conceptions of human nature that stressed choice,
  agency, performance, and desire. Strong metaphors of society were
  supplanted by weaker ones. Imagined collectivities shrank; notions of
  structure and power thinned out. Viewed by its acts of mind, the last
  quarter of the (twentieth) century was an era of disaggregation, a
  great age of fracture. (Rodgers, 2011, 3)

If this is right, it follows that the task of solving our economic problems requires us to go deeper than simply working out a new set of policies for economic growth: if such policies are to be possible, our hollowed-out vision of capitalism, in which there is indeed no such thing as society, needs to be replaced with something much richer, for without it there will be no foundation on which the case for reform can be based.

But what has this got to do with Keynes? Keynes has been rejected because he has been seen as no more than the purveyor of a technical remedy for depression whose prescription has been rendered irrelevant by the growing debt crisis: because of high debt, the world cannot afford the luxury of continued deficit spending. Keynesian economics is part of the welfare state, something that, even if it is not acceptable to say so openly, we cannot afford.

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Keynes after the Crisis
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Welcome to the new Questia Reader

The Questia Reader has been updated to provide you with an even better online reading experience.  It is now 100% Responsive, which means you can read our books and articles on any sized device you wish.  All of your favorite tools like notes, highlights, and citations are still here, but the way you select text has been updated to be easier to use, especially on touchscreen devices.  Here's how:

1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
2. Click or tap the last word you want to select.

OK, got it!

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.