Climate Change

By Bhaduri, Amit | The Economic and Labour Relations Review : ELRR, September 2012 | Go to article overview

Climate Change


Bhaduri, Amit, The Economic and Labour Relations Review : ELRR


Introduction

Like vegetation that changes with climatic conditions, economic policies too change with another kind of climate, the climate of economic opinion. Although similar to the extent that both are consequences of industrialism, changes in the climate of economic policy impact more directly and immediately on our everyday life. And yet, they are seldom noticed and rarely commented upon critically. The change in the climate of opinion is usually brought about by governments, a sufficiently pliable media beholden to them, and their equally pliable economic experts who enjoy proximity to political power and influence by association. The changes in policy and the economic reforms are then presented to the public as compulsions of the day. The changes can then go largely unopposed under the syndrome of TINA (There Is No Alternative) (Thatcher 1987).

Things are more direct when political power is heavily concentrated. Fascism required state power to be under the control of big business, official communism wanted it under 'the dictatorship of the proletariat' (read the Communist Party). Between these extremes lies the spectrum of liberal democracy which comes in an almost bewildering variety, from social democracy inclined towards economic activism of the state and regulation of markets to the minimalist state inclined towards laissez faire and unrestrained freedom for the market.

Nevertheless the various shades of capitalist democracies have one common underlying presumption which has been at the core of the wide-spread legitimacy it enjoys. The state, it is assumed, would maintain a sufficient degree of neutrality to balance conflicting interests of contending classes and groups. The game of liberal democracy cannot be played unless there is a referee. And, the state has to act as the referee to let the fortune of conflicting class interests fluctuate within manageable limits. Like a pendulum it would swing, but the swing will be calibrated, avoiding extremes.

Both market capitalism and political democracy are celebrated as widening the scope of choice. The freedom to choose in an unregulated market is considered a necessary concomitant to the freedom to choose the government. In popular imagination coloured by the media one does not exist without the other. And yet, the logic of the market depends on 'one dollar one vote' which gives the rich disproportionate power; whereas political democracy of 'one adult one vote' depends on the majority. The two coexist in a market democracy without severe tension when the state acts as a relatively neutral referee among contesting classes and groups in the society.

It was on this assumption of relative neutrality of the state that the theory of demand management in capitalist democracies was developed. It is associated with the name of the British economist John Maynard Keynes, although it was formulated independently around the same time by the Polish economist Michael Kalecki. The theory in a sufficiently vulgarised form became conventional wisdom for statecraft ('We are all Keynesians now' remarked former U.S president Richard Nixon). The theory says that a high level of economic activity, output and employment, can be maintained by the government by keeping aggregate demand at a sufficiently high level. And, aggregate demand can be kept high whenever necessary through government spending financed by budget deficit or borrowing. The political implication of the theory is remarkable for capitalism. High output and employment would benefit both the classes--employers and employees, captains of industry as well as workers; even the self-employed would benefit from a buoyant state of the market. Capitalists and managers can look forward to high profit resulting from high capacity utilisation and a larger volume of sales. Workers can expect larger pay packets and easy availability of jobs at high employment. It is the economic recipe for cooperative rather than conflictive capitalism and provides the ideal setting for class harmony in a liberal democracy. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Climate Change
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.