The Value of Consumer Choice and the Decline in HMO Enrollments

By Wedig, Gerard J. | Economic Inquiry, January 2013 | Go to article overview

The Value of Consumer Choice and the Decline in HMO Enrollments


Wedig, Gerard J., Economic Inquiry


I. INTRODUCTION AND OVERVIEW

Health insurance contracts may restrict consumers' choice of medical provider in order to minimize moral hazard. For example, consumers who are insured for their marginal healthcare expenses have no incentive to enforce price discipline on their own. In this case, insurers may impose this discipline by restricting consumers' choice of medical provider to those who offer competitive prices. (1) This practice, known as "selective contracting" (SC), may have other benefits as well, including channeling consumers to efficient providers and achieving other efficiencies associated with (partial) vertical integration. SC has been utilized by insurers both in the United States and abroad. (2) However, it is not a universal feature of health insurance contracts.

In part, this is because reducing the choice set of medical providers imposes costs on consumers to the extent that consumers assign "option value" to choice (Capps, Dranove, and Satterthwaite 2003). For example, SC was widely employed in the United States by health maintenance organizations (HMOs) and other insurers in the 1990s and appears to have been an important cost control mechanism (Cutler, McClellan, and Newhouse 2000; Robinson and Phibbs 1989). However, most private U.S. health insurers moderated their use of SC during the past decade, at the same time that healthcare costs accelerated. Anecdotally, a consumer and regulatory "backlash" against provider choice restrictions forced insurers to expand choice and largely abandon the practice (Blendon et al., 1998; Vita 2001). Simultaneously, HMO enrollments declined.

The purpose of this article is to explore the economic tradeoffs of SC with a particular focus on directly measuring the value that consumers assign to choice in medical markets. I am interested in assessing whether the magnitude of any utility loss from choice restrictions can be offset by volume-based price discounts that insurers may receive from hospitals. My results bear on the larger question of whether an economic linkage can be drawn between consumers' demand for choice and their apparent rejection of what is called "tightly managed care." They also have implications for many healthcare reform proposals that necessarily imply restrictions on the consumers' choice sets.

I analyze health plan's SC of hospitals in the state of Florida between 1999 and 2003. Hospital SC restricts consumer choice in multiple ways including their choice of hospital. In addition, hospital choice restrictions imply restrictions over the use of specific physicians. (3) I start by constructing hospital networks for each of a set of plan choices and then estimate a discrete choice model of health insurance demand, conditional on each plan's restricted network. For these purposes I use the Capps, Dranove, and Satterthwaite (2003) measure of SC disutility that focuses on the "option value" of choice. I employ several different discrete choice estimators to estimate the model, including models with plan-metropolitan statistical area (MSA) fixed effects designed to control for unobserved plan attributes. This provides me with estimates of disutility resulting from choice restrictions. Subsequently, I project the estimated plan effects onto an instrumented value of plan price in order to estimate the price elasticity and also convert my disutility estimates into dollars.

My results show that consumers associated restrictive hospital networks with plan disutility during each of the years of the study period with choice elasticities that range from -0.10 to -0.32 in pooled estimates (greater effects are obtained in 2003 using models where I allow the estimates to vary by year). Using my instrumental variables methodology to recover unbiased price coefficients, I show that consumers associated a one standard deviation reduction in the size of a plan's hospital network with a reduction in plan value of between $62 and $118. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

The Value of Consumer Choice and the Decline in HMO Enrollments
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Welcome to the new Questia Reader

The Questia Reader has been updated to provide you with an even better online reading experience.  It is now 100% Responsive, which means you can read our books and articles on any sized device you wish.  All of your favorite tools like notes, highlights, and citations are still here, but the way you select text has been updated to be easier to use, especially on touchscreen devices.  Here's how:

1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
2. Click or tap the last word you want to select.

OK, got it!

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.