Optimizing English and American Security Interests

By LoPucki, Lynn M.; Abraham, Arvin I. et al. | Notre Dame Law Review, April 2013 | Go to article overview

Optimizing English and American Security Interests


LoPucki, Lynn M., Abraham, Arvin I., Delahaye, Bernd P., Notre Dame Law Review


INTRODUCTION

Security is a relationship between collateral and monetary obligations. The essence of the relationship is that if the obligations are not paid, the collateral may be sold and the sale proceeds applied to pay the obligations. The security concept is embodied in mortgages, security interests, and liens.

Security enjoys a highly privileged position in American law. A simple-sentence grant of a security interest, (1) combined with the filing of notice in an obscure set of public records, will give the secured creditor's claim priority over employees' wage claims, (2) child support obligations, (3) tax claims, (4) civil damage judgments, (5) criminal fines and forfeitures, (6) claims for unjust enrichment, (7) and just about any other kind of debt imaginable. (8)

Scholars have attempted to justify security on both contract and property theories. On the American side, Dean David Leebron best articulated the contract argument:

   The priority claim of a secured creditor rests almost entirely on
   principles of contract and notice. A persuasive theory of secured
   credit financing has been elusive, but the priority of a secured
   creditor over other financial creditors can be justified on the
   grounds that non-secured creditors grant a loan knowing that some
   assets are subject to security interests or could be subjected to
   security interests without their permission. If particular
   creditors will not tolerate other creditors having security
   interests in the borrower's assets, they can refuse to make a loan
   or make it only if the borrower agrees not to subject its assets to
   any security interests. (9)

Contract cannot, however, justify security because security agreements "[are] effective according to [their] terms ... against purchasers of the collateral, and against creditors." (10) That includes purchasers and creditors who did not consent to the security agreement, had no way of knowing of its existence, or never chose to become creditors at all. (11) Agreement is the essence of contract, but the affected purchasers and creditors have not agreed. As Professors Lynn LoPucki and Elizabeth Warren put it, "[s]ecurity is an agreement between A and B that C take nothing." (12)

Other scholars attempt to justify security on property theories. For example, Professors Stephen Harris and Charles Mooney argued:

   It seems clear enough that security interests, under Article 9 and
   real estate law alike, are interests in property. The legal regime
   for security interests reflects property law functionally as well
   as doctrinally. We believe it follows that the law should honor the
   transfer or retention of security interests on the same normative
   grounds on which it respects the alienation of property generally.
   (13)

The property theory begins from the generally accepted premise that a building owner can, by conveying the building in an otherwise unobjectionable transaction, cut off the rights of the debtor's creditors to the building. By analogy, the property theory holds that by conveying the first $100,000 of the value of the building in return for a $100,000 loan, the owner should be able to cut off the rights of the debtor's other creditors to the first $100,000 of the value of the building. Frequent American literature references to security interests as "property" (14) and English literature references to charges as "proprietary" (15) are invocations of this theory.

A necessary implication of the property conveyance theory is that encumbered property has multiple owners. The secured creditor owns the value of the collateral up to the full amount of the debt. The debtor owns the value of the collateral in excess of the amount of the debt, the right to redeem the property by paying the debt, (16) and the right to use the property in the interim.

The principal policy objections to security are that it is deceptive (17) (the "Deception Problem") and that it distorts incentives for the management of property (the "Incentives Problem"). …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Optimizing English and American Security Interests
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.