The Monetary Exception: Labour, Distribution and Money in Capitalism

By Mann, Geoff | Capital & Class, June 2013 | Go to article overview

The Monetary Exception: Labour, Distribution and Money in Capitalism


Mann, Geoff, Capital & Class


Introduction

Samuel Gompers is well known for lots of reasons, but one of them is certainly his famous response to the question, 'What does labour want?'--to which he replied, 'More'. His answer leaves considerable room for interpretation, of course, but certainly one of the messages is, 'We want more of what they have'. Whether Gompers thought it was a zero-sum game or not is unclear (he may very well have thought so), but it makes perfect sense either way: it is more than possible for 'us' to have more without depriving 'them' of anything more than the distance between us. The point was merely that the things capital enjoys--wealth, power, dignity, security, freedom--should also be enjoyed by labour. These 'things' have, ultimately, always been the stakes in the struggle between capital and labour. One of them, however, has usually been a priority, since it is generally considered the means to the others: money. While other 'things', such as the length of the working day, gender parity or shop-floor control, have often been at stake, the division of the surplus is the fundamental site of struggle. In modern capitalism, this boils down to where, and to whom, the money flows, and how it accumulates.

This struggle is premised on a tacit but absolutely essential assumption: that the stakes--income and wealth, and all the things that flow from them--can simply be redistributed without affecting the work they do; that the form wealth takes is not a function of its mode of distribution. It is to assume that the direction of the flow of monetary income and wealth (at present, increasingly toward capital) is itself not part of what makes it work as income and wealth. The idea seems to be that modern money can be governed so as to make anyone rich--worker or boss--and rich in basically the same way.

But this may not in fact be the case. In capitalism, money as it currently works takes particular forms and serves particular functions that make it capital-tropic at its core (Weber 1978: 79; Ingham 2004: 78-81). This paper concerns the implications of this possibility and is focused, necessarily at a rather abstract, institutional scale, on how money works in contemporary financialised neoliberal capitalism. (Below, I try to be as precise as possible with each of these over-used terms.) I argue that much of the critique that animates labour studies--a critique that animates labour politics broadly--has a tendency to imagine that the main problem with capitalism is that the capitalists are in charge. The corollary is that the distributional questions at the centre of a labour-based critique are mostly a question of restructuring the hierarchy via something like 'democratisation'. But significant elements of the modern capitalist political economy, regardless of who is in the driver's seat, are constitutively non- or anti-democratic. It is not a matter of merely remaking them democratically, since if they were democratic, or 'democratisable', they literally would not be what they are. The institution on which I focus, modern capitalist money, is a case in point: it is non-democratic by definition, and it constrains in its very being what redistribution can mean today. Money in capitalism cannot just be redistributed to labour according to an ethical rule of thumb, ceteris paribus. The institutional and political bases of money as a social relation in contemporary capitalism militate against this.

Money-in-capitalism thus cannot be approached as class-, geography-, or history-neutral. That may seem to state the obvious, so it bears emphasising that my point is not aimed at the quantitative maldistribution of purchasing power and monetary wealth across different classes, spaces and times. That is of course a crucial concern, but my argument is more fundamental. It is that there are aspects of money as a modern social relation that operate at a supra-distributional level, and indeed that determine how and to whom it can be distributed, and what it can and cannot be used to do. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

The Monetary Exception: Labour, Distribution and Money in Capitalism
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Welcome to the new Questia Reader

The Questia Reader has been updated to provide you with an even better online reading experience.  It is now 100% Responsive, which means you can read our books and articles on any sized device you wish.  All of your favorite tools like notes, highlights, and citations are still here, but the way you select text has been updated to be easier to use, especially on touchscreen devices.  Here's how:

1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
2. Click or tap the last word you want to select.

OK, got it!

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.