Merton Miller and Modern Finance

By Stulz, Rene M. | Financial Management, Winter 2000 | Go to article overview

Merton Miller and Modern Finance


Stulz, Rene M., Financial Management


Rene M. Stulz [*]

In this keynote address to the 2000 Financial Management Association International Annual Meeting, I consider Merton Miller's contributions to the field of finance. I argue that his most important contribution is to have made arbitrage arguments the cornerstone of modern finance. The arbitrage proof of Proposition I introduced a new standard in finance, namely that any result the finance profession takes seriously must have the critical property that it cannot be undermined by clever arbitrageurs. I show how arbitrage is a constant theme in Merton Miller's career from his work in corporate finance to his analyses of financial innovation, financial crashes, and crises.

Most of us learned first about how much finance owes to Merton Miller in our Ph.D. studies. I was lucky to be a Ph.D. student at MIT in the late 1970s. Throughout my studies, Merton Miller seemed omnipresent in the courses I took and in his influence on everybody connected with finance. He defined the field and shaped it by his actions. When we talked about the BlackScholes formula, Merton Miller had played an important role in getting the paper published after it had been turned down by two journals. He had taken Fischer Black, who was then at MIT, from his work as a consultant to make him a full professor at the University of Chicago. In Robert Merton's asset pricing course, we learned that Merton Miller had defined the rules for empirical tests of the capital asset pricing model in his critique of the Douglas study with Myron Scholes. In Stewart Myers' corporate finance course, we obviously talked about the Modigliani-Miller papers, but at that time corporate finance's attention was turned to Merton Mille r's address as president of the American Finance Association. Even in monetary economics courses, he was there in full force with one of his most beautiful papers, the Miller and Upton model of the demand for money.

For the 20 years after I received my Ph.D., finance was a field young enough that most of its founding fathers were active and still influencing its development. At the center of these founding fathers stood Merton Miller. For many people in finance, he played a key role in their career. Obviously, this was the case for the large number of Ph.D. students whose dissertation he supervised. Many of these students became stars in our profession - one received a Nobel prize. However, besides his students, he had a direct impact on many careers. Even though I never took a course from him, he was one of my most important finance teachers. I spent one year at the University of Chicago. I discovered early in that year that I could learn a lot of finance by joining Merton Miller's lunch group at the faculty club. In addition to learning finance, I learned about all sorts of other things, because he was always fascinating. He was an important reason why I became editor of the Journal of Finance, and he never stopped he lping me during my years as editor. Even when his influence was not direct and personal, it was never possible to do much in finance without being reminded of his contributions and of his presence. He was always there, trying to push forward the field that he had played such a key role in creating. Nobody else deployed such energy and skills in advancing our profession. Even in his last stay at the hospital, he was still concerned about mistakes he thought were being made that he had to correct. At that point, he had finished the first draft of a paper and was waiting to go back home to finish it and submit it to a journal.

We can list many reasons why Merton Miller was so important to our field, but his contribution to our field transcends the list of his accomplishments. He was unique, and so we have to focus on why he was so unique. If we had to remember one thing about Merton Miller's contribution to finance, what would it be? Many financial economists are likely to answer that question by saying that we should remember the irrelevance propositions. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Merton Miller and Modern Finance
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.