Demystifying Antitrust State Action Doctrine

By Semeraro, Steven | Harvard Journal of Law & Public Policy, Fall 2000 | Go to article overview

Demystifying Antitrust State Action Doctrine


Semeraro, Steven, Harvard Journal of Law & Public Policy


Sometimes the most mystifying thing about legal doctrine is why so many commentators find it so mystifying. And so it is with antitrust state action doctrine. The federal antitrust laws do not apply to business activities that are the foreseeable result of a state regulatory program so long as public actors, as opposed to private ones, supervise the conduct in question. Commentators aplenty have bemoaned the doctrine's theoretical incoherence -- labeling it a practical mess that cannot be applied predictably.(1) The Court, they say, has simply failed to articulate a coherent theory to differentiate its conflicting decisions. For example, the doctrine has been used to exempt from antitrust scrutiny colluding motor carriers,(2) but not colluding insurance carriers,(3) even though both were subject to state regulatory schemes. At least four major law review articles have attempted to explain existing antitrust state action doctrine.(4) Unfortunately, they rely on four different theories and propose four different tests to determine when state regulation exempts private parties from federal antitrust scrutiny.

This theoretical ambiguity does not bode well for the myriad state-federal regulatory conflicts destined to arise in the next century. New approaches to telecommunications convergence,(5) efforts to regulate internet commerce,(6) and continued deregulation of utilities(7) are but three examples sure to lead to regulatory schemes with varying goals and techniques that differ widely among states and municipalities as well as the federal government.

For example, suppose that a state seeks to regulate advertising on the start-up pages of internet service providers. Advertising restrictions ordinarily raise serious antitrust concerns,(8) and antitrust surely will play a role in evaluating such a regulated environment. But when will antitrust doctrine lead regulatory policy? When will it support other policy considerations? And when should it get out of the way? To avoid a hopeless legal tangle over the line where regulation ends and antitrust begins (or is it the other way around?), a clear theory explaining antitrust state action doctrine must be found.

This Article has two purposes: (1) to articulate a descriptive theory to explain current antitrust state action doctrine, and (2) to evaluate that theory on normative grounds in comparison to the alternative theories and tests suggested by prior commentators. As to the descriptive project, the Article demystifies current antitrust state action doctrine by showing that it distinguishes government actors who are trusted to advance the collective good from businesspersons whose decisions are intended to advance their own interest in maximizing profit.(9) The doctrine is a by-product of our society's longstanding belief in two spheres of decisionmaking, public and private. This social organization, which might be called the status choice model assumes that individuals can choose to further either public-interested goals or self-interested goals, and social welfare can be maximized by dual spheres of public-interested governmental decisionmaking and self-interested private decisionmaking, each governed by appropriate background rules. Criticism of antitrust state action doctrine has invariably missed this distinction and -- implicitly or explicitly -- assumed that public actors seek to serve selfish interests just like private actors do.(10) No wonder current doctrine appears so mystifying to so many commentators.

As to the normative project, this Article concludes that current doctrine as explained by the status choice model provides an understandable and satisfying way to distinguish permissible from impermissible state regulation given modern American society's dual belief in self-interested private decisionmaking and public-interested government decisionmaking. Although one may fault current doctrine for requiring judges to rely on inherently uncertain intuitions about the extent and importance of government involvement in regulatory decisions, this intuitive test is as practical as any of the alternatives. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Demystifying Antitrust State Action Doctrine
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Welcome to the new Questia Reader

The Questia Reader has been updated to provide you with an even better online reading experience.  It is now 100% Responsive, which means you can read our books and articles on any sized device you wish.  All of your favorite tools like notes, highlights, and citations are still here, but the way you select text has been updated to be easier to use, especially on touchscreen devices.  Here's how:

1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
2. Click or tap the last word you want to select.

OK, got it!

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.