The International Gold Standard and U.S. Monetary Policy from World War I to the New Deal

By Crabbe, Leland | Federal Reserve Bulletin, June 1989 | Go to article overview

The International Gold Standard and U.S. Monetary Policy from World War I to the New Deal


Crabbe, Leland, Federal Reserve Bulletin


The International Gold Standard and U.S. Monetary Policy from World War I to the New Deal

Before the First World War, most of the world, including the United States, Great Britain, and every country in Europe, maintained gold standard. In the United States, the Resumption Act had restored the gold standard in 1879, and the Gold Standard Act of 1900 had established gold as the ultimate standard of value. Internationally, the gold standard committed the United States to maintain a fixed exchange rate in relation to other countries on the gold standard, a commitment that facilitated the flow of goods and capital among countries. Domestically, the gold standard committed the United States to limit the expansion of money and credit, and thus it restrained inflationary pressures.

The international gold standard did not function ideally, however. Although the gold standard provided a basis for nominal stability over the long run, the U.S. and world economy suffered in the short run through periods of depression and inflation due to changes in the world's supply of and demand for gold. Moreover, the U.S. commitment to the international gold standard had a cost: It confined, though it did not preclude, discretionary management of the domestic economy.

From the First World War to the New Deal, amid upheaval in international and domestic financial markets, the United States honored its commitment to redeem dollars for gold at $20.67 per ounce. Maintenance of the gold standard, however, recurrently interfered with the Federal Reserve's broader objective of stabilizing the domestic economy. During the First World War, the United States and other belligerents fully or partly suspended the gold standard, de jure or de facto, to prevent it from hampering the war effort. In 1920, when the United States alone operated the gold standard without restrictions, the Federal Reserve imposed a severe monetary contraction, which defended the gold standard but contributed greatly to a depression. Hoping to stabilize the world economy in the 1920s, the industrial nations, notably Britain and France, restored the international gold standard. The restoration--which must be judged a failure--compelled the Federal Reserve to make choices between its international and its domestic objectives. Indeed, throughout the 1920s and early 1930s, Federal Reserve policy alternated between management of the international gold standard and management of the domestic economy. With the devaluation of the dollar in 1933, the United States established the principle that domestic policy objectives had primacy over the dictates of the gold standard. (See table 1 for the major events covered in this paper and the insert on page 425 for definitions of terms regarding the gold standard.)

THE FIRST WORLD WAR

The First World War nearly demolished the international gold standard. While none of the countries at war demonetized gold or refused to buy gold at a fixed price, none adhered strictly to the tenets of the gold standard. When the war began, belligerent governments instituted several legal and practical changes in the gold standard, which they viewed as a temporary suspension of the rules rather than as a permanent abandonment of the international monetary system. Previous wars had often forced suspension; peace had always brought restoration.

U.S. Response to the 1914 Crisis

Although the United States did not enter the war until 1917, the outbreak of war in Europe in 1914 immediately disrupted U.S. financial and commodity markets, the latter being heavily dependent on London for the financing of exports. In July 1914, U.S. firms had a large amount of short-term debts payable in Europe, primarily in London; but this position was normal in the summer, as borrowers expected to use the proceeds from exports of cotton and grain to pay off their liabilities in the fall. As Europe moved toward war, the world's financial markets became highly disorganized, especially after acceptance and discount houses in London shut down their operations.

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

The International Gold Standard and U.S. Monetary Policy from World War I to the New Deal
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Welcome to the new Questia Reader

The Questia Reader has been updated to provide you with an even better online reading experience.  It is now 100% Responsive, which means you can read our books and articles on any sized device you wish.  All of your favorite tools like notes, highlights, and citations are still here, but the way you select text has been updated to be easier to use, especially on touchscreen devices.  Here's how:

1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
2. Click or tap the last word you want to select.

OK, got it!

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.