An Economic Analysis of Aspects of Petroleum and Military Security in the Persian Gulf

By Chapman, Duane; Khanna, Neha | Contemporary Economic Policy, October 2001 | Go to article overview

An Economic Analysis of Aspects of Petroleum and Military Security in the Persian Gulf


Chapman, Duane, Khanna, Neha, Contemporary Economic Policy


NEHA KHANNA (*)

Geologic estimates of remaining global petroleum resources place about 50% in the Persian Gulf. Production costs are estimated at $5 per barrel there and $15 per barrel in the North Sea and Alaska. According to mathematical results derived from depletion theory, the present value of economic rent from oil is on the order of $20 trillion. This article uses game theory to explain the $15-$20 per barrel price band that existed from 1986 to 1999. New economic forces have displaced this previously stable pattern; a new price range of $23-$30 is emerging. International trade in petroleum and conventional weapons are analyzed with econometric methods; the occurrence of nuclear weapons capability in the Persian Gulf region is explored. (JEL C61, Q32, Q41, 043, 048)

I. INTRODUCTION

In 1980, shortly after Saddam Hussein assumed the presidency of Iraq, that country attacked Iran in the southwest Khuzistan region. Iraq sought control over two major geographic goals: the Shatt-al-Arab channel, a shipping route for export of Iraqi oil, and the petroleum production facilities in Khuzistan, where more than 75% of Iran's oil resources were located (Yergin, 1991; International Petroleum Encyclopedia, 1983).

In 1990, Iraq occupied Kuwait and threatened Saudi Arabia. If Iraq had been successful in these military actions, it would have controlled 40% of identified global reserves and 75% of Persian Gulf reserves (see Table 1).

In 1991, U.S. president George H. Bush supported a U.S.-led United Nations (UN) military coalition that defeated Iraq, emphasizing that "[o]ur jobs, our way of life, our own freedom and the freedom of friendly countries around the world would all suffer if control of the world's great oil reserves fell into the hands of Saddam Hussein" (Yergin, 1991, 773). This military action eliminated Iraq's potential to raise crude oil prices and attain quasi-monopolistic profits. Yet five years earlier, then Vice President Bush had flown to the Persian Gulf, meeting with Saudi government ministers and the king. The purpose of this 1986 trip had been to raise crude oil prices, which at the time were below $10 per barrel.

The purpose of the following analysis is to illuminate part of the economic rationale for these superficially contradictory U.S. policies. It shall show the magnitude of the economic incentives for control of Persian Gulf oil and show the logic which led the United States and some other Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) nations to work against crude oil prices below $15 per barrel and above $20 per barrel for a 13-year period from 1986 through 1999. The same incentives operate now to create a new, higher price range of potentially comparable stability.

The first section identifies the magnitude of economic rent (defined below), which partially motivates foreign policies of the Gulf countries and the United States. It uses game theory logic to explain the $15-$20 per barrel range within which crude oil prices usually moved. The next section analyzes the framework now evolving toward a new price range. The third part analyzes global military trade in the context of petroleum imports and exports. Next appears a brief summary of the growth in nuclear weapons capability in the region, followed by a summary of the pre-1980 history of Gulf production and international relations. A discussion of implications for the early part of this century, and the likelihood of a new near-term price range, concludes the study.

II. PETROLEUM PRICE, RENT, AND GAME THEORY, 1986-1999

In the petroleum economics literature, $5 per barrel is widely used as the likely equilibrium price in a theoretically competitive world oil market working without production quota agreements (Adelman, 1986, 1993; Economist, 1999; Yergin, 1991).

Table 2 illustrates the production cost in a low-cost area in the Persian Gulf and in the North Sea. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

An Economic Analysis of Aspects of Petroleum and Military Security in the Persian Gulf
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Welcome to the new Questia Reader

The Questia Reader has been updated to provide you with an even better online reading experience.  It is now 100% Responsive, which means you can read our books and articles on any sized device you wish.  All of your favorite tools like notes, highlights, and citations are still here, but the way you select text has been updated to be easier to use, especially on touchscreen devices.  Here's how:

1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
2. Click or tap the last word you want to select.

OK, got it!

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.