Interest Rates and the Foreclosure Process: An Agency Problem in FHA Mortgage Insurance

By Clauretie, Terrence M.; Jameson, Mel | Journal of Risk and Insurance, December 1990 | Go to article overview

Interest Rates and the Foreclosure Process: An Agency Problem in FHA Mortgage Insurance


Clauretie, Terrence M., Jameson, Mel, Journal of Risk and Insurance


Interest Rates and the Foreclosure Process: an Agency Problem in FHA Mortgage Insurance

Unlike private mortgage insurance that establishes a coinsurance relationship with the lender, Federal Housing Administration (FHA) insurance provides full coverage of all losses including foregone interest on defaulted loans. The foregone interest component of the indemnity is at the original mortgage contract rate. This arrangment offers lenders an opportunity to exploit changes in interest rates. Specifically, lenders have an incentive to expedite (slow) the foreclosure process when the market rate is above (below) the contract rate. If the market rate is above the contract rate, the lender will expedite the process (within the constraints of the legal requirements) and reinvest the indemnity at a higher rate. Conversely, if the market rate falls below the contract rate, the lender is better off by slowing the process (again, within the constraints of legal parameters) because the loan balance earns the higher contract rate. Evidence presented below shows that this behavior can be costly to the FHA. A 10 percent decrease in interest rates (say from 10 percent to 9 percent) costs the FHA an estimated $1,151 per claim.

Numerous examples of agency problems exist in financial contracting (see Jensen and Meckling [1976]). In real estate contracts in particular, examples of agency problems include borrower maintenance of property facing foreclosure, covenants included in mortgages (Smith, 1982), and terms of shopping center leases (Benjamin, Boyle, and Sirmans, 1990).

Similarly, agency problems associated with insurance contracts have been noted (see Mayers and Smith, 1981). Mulherin and Muller (1988) pose an incentive conflict whereby lenders have no motivation to expend costly effort to make repairs on foreclosed properties. Mulherin and Muller (1987) note the possibility that lenders may encourage default (rather than continued performance through a workout) on a fully insured mortgage that is in danger of default. As is true of the present study, the incentive conflict results from a divergence of the market and contract rate. They conclude that a rise in the market rate will lead to more defaults as lenders seek to improve the quality of their loan portfolios. They conclude a rise in rates is, therefore, costly to the FHA. In the current study the conclusion is different since the focus is on the post-default incentive conflict. That is, given a default and a rise in rates, the lender has an incentive to foreclose as quickly as possible. A quick foreclosure minimizes the total claim including carrying costs such as property taxes, hazard insurance, maintenance expenses, and so forth. A fall in rates proves costly in our model.

This article proceeds as follows. The next section discusses the effects of the incentive conflict on the speed of the foreclosure process and the per claim loss for FHA loans. Next, data and methodology are presented. Empirical results are then followed by conclusions.

Lender's Incentives: FHA Insurance

Consider a lender holding a defaulted mortgage loan. After the foreclosure process the lender will submit a claim to the FHA for losses. (In a few cases the lender can assign the loan to the FHA which will, in turn, attempt a workout with the borrower.) Those losses will consist of two parts: foregone interest on the loan balance and property carrying costs such as taxes, insurance, and maintenance expenses. Initially, the lender will not have made expenditures for carrying costs so if the contract rate is above the market rate, there is an incentive to delay the foreclosure process. As carrying costs occur, the lender must meet these out of pocket and get reimbursed at a later date without interest, reducing this incentive to delay. Appendix A demonstrates that the strength of this incentive to delay is negatively related to the market rate of interest. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Interest Rates and the Foreclosure Process: An Agency Problem in FHA Mortgage Insurance
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Welcome to the new Questia Reader

The Questia Reader has been updated to provide you with an even better online reading experience.  It is now 100% Responsive, which means you can read our books and articles on any sized device you wish.  All of your favorite tools like notes, highlights, and citations are still here, but the way you select text has been updated to be easier to use, especially on touchscreen devices.  Here's how:

1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
2. Click or tap the last word you want to select.

OK, got it!

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.