The Complexity Vision and the Teaching of Economics. (Book Reviews)

By Hodgson, Geoffrey M. | Review of Social Economy, September 2002 | Go to article overview

The Complexity Vision and the Teaching of Economics. (Book Reviews)


Hodgson, Geoffrey M., Review of Social Economy


The Complexity Vision and the Teaching of Economics. Edited by David C. Colander. Cheltenham, Edward Elgar, 2000, xvi + 307pp., $95.00 (hardcover), ISBN 1-84064-252-1.

This book is an impressive collection of essays emanating from a 1998 conference held at Middlebury College, Vermont, U.S.A. The authors address the impact of the "new science of complexity" on economics and its teaching.

In his introduction, David Colander explains that like all sciences, complexity involves the search for simplicity. However, complexity theory searches for simplicity not in the underlying structures of reality, but in the iterative and dynamic processes that create complex phenomena. In this and other respects, complexity theory complements and enhances, rather than replaces, much of existing science.

Perhaps because this volume addresses the teaching of economics in the light of complexity, as well as complexity itself, most of the essays adopt a clear, presentational style. The first part of the book serves largely to introduce some of the key ideas. In Chapter one, W. Brian Arthur discusses some of the basic elements of complexity thinking: increasing returns, positive feedback, out-of-equilibrium states, and emergent properties. In Chapter two, William Brock introduces some further key concepts, such as scaling laws, self-similarity and self-organised criticality. Brian Arthur returns in the third chapter to address the more specific issue of cognition in economics. This chapter takes a different but complementary tack, discussing how we attribute meaning to complex phenomena. Frederic Pryor takes an imaginary and entertaining view of complexity theory from the year 2028.

Two essays in the second part of the book discuss the implications for economic policy. In chapter five, William Brock and David Colander show that arguments for both laissez faire and government intervention can be derived from the literature on complexity. They make the important point that the complexity vision shifts the debate over policy from deductive models to empirically and historically grounded studies. In contrast, Roger Koppl argues in the following chapter that complexity theory, insofar as it reflects the insights of Austrian school economics, implies that the role of the state in the economy should be highly limited.

The remainder of this volume addresses general and specific issues involved in the teaching of complexity ideas. The contributions here are by David Colander, Roger Koppl, James Stodder, Duncan Foley, Robert Prasch, Kevin Hoover, Sunder Ramaswamy, J. Barkley Rosser, Peter Hans Matthews, Stephen Magee and Michael Rothschild. These essays contain many insights on how students can be taught to use data constructively, rather than rely on pure deduction. It is argued that students should be taught to discern patterns and regularities in data, and then seek explanations using insights from complexity theory and elsewhere.

For this reviewer, the most interesting essays in this latter half of the book are by Kevin Hoover (which contains an insightful discussion of the relationship between macro and micro) and by Barkley Rosser (who makes the point that earlier alleged "fads" such a catastrophe theory and chaos theory are linked to complexity theory by a common emphasis on disequilibria and nonlinearities).

Interestingly, both David Colander and Michael Rothschild discuss why the "learning curve"--a concept widely familiar to business people, managers and others--is absent from the economics texts. The learning curve expresses the idea that productivity increases because people learn through time. Yet this is a dynamic concept, undermining static equilibrium and undermining standard views on competition. It is arguably for these reasons that it is neglected.

Overall, this is a very useful volume because it simultaneously attempts to elaborate the "complexity vision" and to consider how ideas on complexity can be taught to students of economics.

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

The Complexity Vision and the Teaching of Economics. (Book Reviews)
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Welcome to the new Questia Reader

The Questia Reader has been updated to provide you with an even better online reading experience.  It is now 100% Responsive, which means you can read our books and articles on any sized device you wish.  All of your favorite tools like notes, highlights, and citations are still here, but the way you select text has been updated to be easier to use, especially on touchscreen devices.  Here's how:

1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
2. Click or tap the last word you want to select.

OK, got it!

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.