Energy Economics with Eyes Open

By Pecquet, Ashton J.; Pecquet, Gary M. | Ideas on Liberty, February 2002 | Go to article overview

Energy Economics with Eyes Open


Pecquet, Ashton J., Pecquet, Gary M., Ideas on Liberty


Energy is a scarce resource. No one was ever able to have all the energy he wanted. It is neither free nor a gift of nature. Someone must spend labor, wealth, and time to find, produce, and use it. In short, energy is an economic problem.

Of course, energy is a vital economic resource. It is needed for power, transportation, industry, and almost every other human endeavor. It is the lifeblood not only of a modern society, but of any society. This importance, however, does not remove energy from the scope of economics; it only makes economic analysis all the more essential.

The many dimensions of the energy problem can be illustrated by asking a few questions. How much energy do we want and what are we willing to give up for it? Do we want to work longer hours or divert capital from other uses to get more energy? From which sources should our energy come? We can obtain it from coal, oil, natural gas, nuclear reactors, electric batteries, windmills, horses and mules, or from any combination of these sources. But which combination and in what proportions? Where do we want to use our energy? We can use it in industry, transportation, or heating, or we can have some of each. But how much? And which specific industries, modes of transportation, and methods of heating should we use?

These questions present us with a problem, because there are an infinite number of answers to each question. The best answer can only be found when we are able to compare the costs and benefits of each alternative available to us. And since we are dealing with heterogeneous resources, costs and benefits can only be compared with the aid of a common denominator-a price. With this in mind, let us examine alternate social systems to find the one best equipped to economize our energy.

First, there is complete socialism. Its defining characteristic is the public ownership of all the means and resources of production. In light of the collapse of the Soviet Union and its satellites, the suggestion of a pure socialist economy seems foolish. But why must socialism fail? Did the Soviet planners merely suffer from poor judgment or is there a systemic flaw in a publicly owned economy? About 80 years ago, Ludwig von Mises, in his great work Socialism, explained why totalitarian central planning cannot economize resources. By examining a system that fails, perhaps we can find the necessary ingredient for a successful economic system.

Under a system of only one voice, no buying or selling among resource owners is possible. Buying and selling presuppose more than one voice, more than one man or group, seeking gain. Without the buying and selling of resources there can be no resource prices under socialism, except for meaningless arbitrary ones used for bookkeeping. Because there can be no resource prices, the relative values of heterogeneous raw materials, assortments of capital goods, and different types of labor cannot be found. Costs and benefits cannot be compared between resources. The socialist directors would not know if they are profiting or losing. They would not know by performing an action if they were serving consumers better or worse. Hence, socialism does not provide a method for economizing our energy.

To illustrate the dilemma of a socialist, I shall recall the childhood game "pin the tail on the donkey." Each participant was blindfolded and told to pin a donkey tail on a donkey's picture. The one coming closest to the place where the tail should go-the optimal spot-won the contest.

Without prices a socialist is blindfolded also. If you were a socialist director, how would you direct the economy? You have every economic resource at your disposal, but you cannot know which ones are more expensive and by how much. You are blindfolded to price-to the cost of attaining your objectives.

Copying the Market

You can use as a gauge the prices of other nations that have markets. But that is cheating-do not look under the blindfold. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Energy Economics with Eyes Open
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.