Empirical Research with a Policy Payoff: Market Dynamics for Lawyers Who Represent Plaintiffs for a Contingent Fee

By Schneyer, Ted | Texas Law Review, June 2002 | Go to article overview

Empirical Research with a Policy Payoff: Market Dynamics for Lawyers Who Represent Plaintiffs for a Contingent Fee


Schneyer, Ted, Texas Law Review


Many excellent empirical studies of law practice have been conducted over the years, mostly focusing on practice in various workplaces,1 locales,2 specialties,3 or forums.4 These studies have unquestionably enriched our understanding of law practice and the American legal profession, but their impact on public policy is less clear. Because empirical research is costly, one would expect funding sources to be vitally interested in the practical payoff of the studies they support. Yet surprisingly few studies directly address policy issues or provide data that have influenced or seem likely to influence public policy as it bears on professional regulation or access to legal services. Steve Daniels and Joanne Martin's study of Texas "plaintiffs' IMAGE FORMULA4

lawyers"5-lawyers who specialize in representing plaintiffs for contingent fees-is a welcome exception.6

A policy debate has been raging for some time regarding both the reasonableness of the fees that plaintiffs' lawyers charge and the manner in which those fees should be regulated.7 A leading critic, Professor Lester Brickman, asserts that, under existing forms of regulation, contingent fees often yield above-normal returns on plaintiffs' lawyers' time.8 Indeed, by his estimate plaintiffs' lawyers earn "no less than $7.5 to $10 billion in unethical, windfall contingency fees" each year!9 Because lawyers in any given locale tend to charge the same contingent-fee rate (e.g., one-third of any recovery) and tend to charge each of their clients at that rate even though the risk of non-recovery10 varies from case to case, Brickman concludes that competition in the field is far from robust,11 and he supports stringent new IMAGE FORMULA6

restrictions on contingent-fee rates, even where statutory fee caps already exist for personal-injury cases.12 Other scholars, notably Professor Kritzer, view matters quite differently.13 Using data available for the mid-1990s, Kritzer estimates the "effective hourly rates" that lawyers earn in contingent-- fee cases.14 He finds that, although a small percentage of plaintiffs' lawyers earn very large incomes, returns from contingent-fee practice overall are similar to what lawyers earn from hourly-fee practice, or "at best" only marginally higher. 15

The Daniels-Martin study sheds new light on this debate, although it does not directly address the magnitude of prevailing contingent-fee rates or the adequacy of existing regulations. The profitability of contingent-fee work depends not only on fee rates, but also on the percentage of claims that result in recoveries, the amounts recovered, and the costs lawyers incur in pursuing recoveries. The debate often seems to proceed on the assumption that the latter variables remain fairly stable over time.16 Daniels and Martin question that assumption. The policymaking value of their study stems precisely from their focus on market dynamics. The study strongly IMAGE FORMULA8

suggests17 that the market for plaintiffs' lawyers' services in Texas between 1995 and 2000 was quite "unstable"18-that tort-case filings, recovery rates and amounts, and lawyers' net incomes all fell, while costs rose. It suggests, too, that these changes were occasioned by local manifestations of a nationwide phenomenon-the "tort reform" movement of the past two decades. On this account, the reduced circumstances of plaintiffs' lawyers in Texas are probably far from unique.

Daniels and Martin conclude that, in contrast to the pre-1990 period, the challenge for many Texas plaintiffs' lawyers during the 1990s was simply "to keep the lights on"19 (i.e., to continue to do plaintiffs' work) in a contracting market.20 Between 1995 and 2000, considerably more lawyers in their survey reduced the percentage of their practices devoted to contingent-- fee work than expanded it.

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Empirical Research with a Policy Payoff: Market Dynamics for Lawyers Who Represent Plaintiffs for a Contingent Fee
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Welcome to the new Questia Reader

The Questia Reader has been updated to provide you with an even better online reading experience.  It is now 100% Responsive, which means you can read our books and articles on any sized device you wish.  All of your favorite tools like notes, highlights, and citations are still here, but the way you select text has been updated to be easier to use, especially on touchscreen devices.  Here's how:

1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
2. Click or tap the last word you want to select.

OK, got it!

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.