Does Copyright Law Promote Creativity? an Empirical Analysis of Copyright's Bounty

By Shih, Raymond; Ku, Ray et al. | Vanderbilt Law Review, November 2009 | Go to article overview

Does Copyright Law Promote Creativity? an Empirical Analysis of Copyright's Bounty


Shih, Raymond, Ku, Ray, Sun, Jiayang, Fan, Yiying, Vanderbilt Law Review


Modern copyright law is based upon a theory: increase copyright protection and you increase the number of creative works available to society. This theory has been the driving force behind an economic vision that has expanded, beyond all recognition, the original law created by the Statute of Anne. And with this expansion, we are told that the costs associated with copyright are worthwhile because of the bounty it produces. What if this theory could be tested? After all, this is not a question of faith or morality, nor is it a statement on how humans should behave; it is a theory about how humans do behave. In this Article, we use statistical analysis to test the theory that increasing copyright protection usually increases the number of new creative works. Relying upon U.S. copyright registrations from 1870 through 2006 as a proxy for the number of works created, we consider how four variables - population, the economy, legal changes, and technology - influenced subsequent copyright registrations. Our findings cast serious doubt on the idea that with copyright law, one size fits all. While individual legal changes may be associated with changes in subsequent copyright registrations, the overall relationship between changes in copyright law and registrations is neither consistent nor completely predictable.

I. INTRODUCTION

In 1841, Thomas Babington Macaulay delivered a speech in the British Parliament in which he famously described copyright as "a tax on readers for the purpose of giving a bounty to writers."1 While critics of copyright law often use this quote as a general objection to copyright, that was not the intent. Macaulay was not opposed to copyright per se. Instead, he was skeptical that a proposal to increase the length of copyright protection would yield much in return. Following this famous quote, Macaulay went on to say:

I admit, however, the necessity of giving a bounty to genius and learning. In order to give such a bounty, I willingly submit even to this severe and burdensome tax. Nay, I am ready to increase the tax, if it can be shown that by so doing I should proportionally increase the bounty. My complaint is, that my hon[orable] and learned [f]riend doubles, triples, quadruples, the tax, and makes scarcely any perceptible addition to the bounty.2

As such, the problem was not copyright itself, nor even the monopoly costs associated with copyright, which he described in that same speech as a necessary evil.3 The problem was that changing copyright law and expanding copyright's exclusive rights might not provide the public with any real benefit. While Macaulay was successful in defeating the 1841 effort to expand copyright,4 more often than not, lawmakers have not shared his skepticism.5

In the United States, the history of copyright law is one of expansion. For example, in 1790, copyright originally provided authors the exclusive right to vend books and maps for fourteen years with an additional fourteen years of protection available through renewal.6 Currently, copyright protects all original expression fixed in a tangible medium of expression, which includes books, motion pictures, sound recordings, broadcasts of sporting events, and video games.7 It provides authors the exclusive right to control almost all uses of their writings - even the ability to create new works based upon the original.8 Moreover, this protection generally lasts for the life of the author plus an additional seventy years.9

The logic behind this expansion is straightforward. Copyright law provides authors with exclusive rights in their works.10 In turn, these exclusive rights allow successful authors to obtain financial reward for their works by creating a market for them instead of forcing them to seek private or government patronage. The greater the protection, the greater the reward; the greater the reward, the greater the incentive to create new works; and the greater the incentive to create new works, the greater the number of new works created.

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Does Copyright Law Promote Creativity? an Empirical Analysis of Copyright's Bounty
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Welcome to the new Questia Reader

The Questia Reader has been updated to provide you with an even better online reading experience.  It is now 100% Responsive, which means you can read our books and articles on any sized device you wish.  All of your favorite tools like notes, highlights, and citations are still here, but the way you select text has been updated to be easier to use, especially on touchscreen devices.  Here's how:

1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
2. Click or tap the last word you want to select.

OK, got it!

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.