Monetary Policy with Interest on Reserves

By Hornstein, Andreas | Economic Quarterly - Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Second Quarter 2010 | Go to article overview

Monetary Policy with Interest on Reserves


Hornstein, Andreas, Economic Quarterly - Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond


(ProQuest: ... denotes formulae omitted.)

In response to the emerging financial crisis of 2008, the Federal Reserve decided to increase the liquidity of the banking system. For this purpose, the Federal Reserve introduced or expanded a number of programs that made it easier for banks to borrow from it. For example, commercial banks were able to obtain additional loans through the Term Auction Facility, which the banks would then hold in their reserve accounts with the Federal Reserve. As a result of the combined financial market interventions, the balance sheet of the Federal Reserve increased from about $800 billion in September 2008 to more than $2 trillion in December 2008. Over the same time period, the reserve accounts of commercial banks with the Federal Reserve increased from about $100 billion to $800 billion. In late 2008 the Federal Reserve also announced a program to purchase mortgage-backed securities (MBS) and debt issued by government-sponsored agencies. Since then, outright purchases of agency MBS and agency debt have essentially replaced short-term borrowing by commercial banks on the asset side of the Federal Reserve's balance sheet, and the volume of outstanding reserves increased again to about $1.1 trillion by the end of 2009. Given the magnitude of outstanding reserves, there is some concern these reserves might limit policy options once the Federal Reserve decides to pursue a more restrictive monetary policy. Yet, another change in the available policy instruments might lessen this concern: Starting in October 2008, the Federal Reserve began to pay interest on the reserve accounts that banks hold with the Federal Reserve System.

How should one think about monetary policy when reserve accounts earn interest? To study this issue, I introduce a stylized banking sector into a simple baseline model of money that is at the core of much research in monetary economics. In this framework I address an admittedly rather narrowtheoretical question, but this question is fundamental to any theory of monetary policy. Namely, does the payment of interest on reserves affect issues of price level determinacy? An indeterminate price level might be undesirable since it can give rise to price level fluctuations driven by self-fulfilling expectations. In this context it is shown that the amount of outstanding reserves has only limited implications for the conduct of monetary policy.

Price level determinacy is studied in a theoretical framework that specifies not only monetary policy, but also fiscal policy, e.g., Leeper (1991) or Sims (1994). Monetary policy is described as setting a short-term nominal interest rate in response to inflation, and fiscal policy is described as setting the primary surplus in response to outstanding government debt. For the baseline monetary model without a banking sector, one obtains price level determinacy if monetary policy is active, that is, it responds strongly to the inflation rate, and fiscal policy is passive, that is, it responds strongly to government debt.1 Price level determinacy is also obtained when monetary policy is passive and fiscal policy is active. For the modified model with a banking sector, I find that this characterization of price level determinacy is not materially affected, whether or not interest is paid on reserves. I obtain a determinate price level when monetary policy is sufficiently active and fiscal policy is sufficiently passive, or vice versa. Furthermore, the magnitude of outstanding reserves may not matter at all, and if it does matter the impact of reserves is small.

Earlier theoretical work on paying interest on reserves was concerned that this policy would lead to price level indeterminacy. Sargent andWallace (1985) argue that, depending on how interest on reserves is financed, an equilibrium might not exist or the price level might be indeterminate.2 In terms of the above characterization of monetary and fiscal policy, these results obtain because the assumed financing schemes for interest on reserves make monetary and fiscal policy both passive or both active.

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Monetary Policy with Interest on Reserves
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Welcome to the new Questia Reader

The Questia Reader has been updated to provide you with an even better online reading experience.  It is now 100% Responsive, which means you can read our books and articles on any sized device you wish.  All of your favorite tools like notes, highlights, and citations are still here, but the way you select text has been updated to be easier to use, especially on touchscreen devices.  Here's how:

1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
2. Click or tap the last word you want to select.

OK, got it!

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.