Dynamic Transaction Costs and Firm Boundaries in the Soft Drink Industry

By Kench, Brian T.; Knox, Trevor M. et al. | Journal of Economics and Economic Education Research, January 1, 2012 | Go to article overview

Dynamic Transaction Costs and Firm Boundaries in the Soft Drink Industry


Kench, Brian T., Knox, Trevor M., Wallace, H. Scott, Journal of Economics and Economic Education Research


ABSTRACT

Recent articles in the business press have drawn attention to firms integrating different stages of their supply chain. This purported increase in vertical mergers and the awarding of a Nobel Prize to Oliver Williamson in 2009 provide an excellent opportunity to reflect on the efficacy of economic theory in explaining shifts in the vertical boundaries of the firm. The dominant approaches emphasize the role of transaction costs and agency costs in determining the optimal level of vertical integration. This paper argues that the narrow focus on incentives by these approaches has ignored the role of organization in coordinating complementary activities that require very different types of know-how. Capabilities theory which stresses the knowledge, skills, and experience of firms contends that it is the transaction costs that emerge from trying to coordinate these types of activities that best explain the vertical boundaries of the firm. This paper argues that the capabilities story best describes the economic rationale for vertical integration (or disintegration). A case study analyzing vertical integration in the carbonated soft drink industry is presented.

INTRODUCTION

There have been numerous articles in the business press identifying an increase in the number of vertical mergers. This increase in activity has sparked a debate over whether these mergers represent a general movement towards vertical integration, reversing several decades of outsourcing and vertical disintegration (Gross, 2006; Denning, 2009). Despite differences in opinion over trends, observers agree that, unlike the large corporations of a hundred years ago, current efforts are not leading to full-blown vertical integration. "Today's approach is more nuanced. Companies are buying key parts of their supply chains but most don't want end-to-end control" (Worthen, et. al., 2009).

These articles have put forth a variety of explanations for this increase in "selective vertical integration" (Gross, 2006). One is that rising commodity prices (and price volatility) have spurred manufacturers to purchase suppliers of commodities. "Having bulked up acquiring rivals, manufacturers are turning their deal making prowess to raw materials providers in hopes of ensuring adequate supplies and controlling costs" (Aeppel, 2006, Al). The current economic downturn has also been cited as an important rationale for backward integration. By threatening the economic viability of suppliers, the recession has created a high degree of uncertainty for downstream firms who rely on upstream producers for inputs and raw materials (The Economist, 2009). For both these situations, backward integration represents a defensive strategy to prevent costly interruptions in the supply chain. Such efforts resemble one of the major rationales for the emergence of large, vertically integrated corporations during the late 19th and early 20th centuries (Chandler, 1977).

In addition to ensuring supplies, a recent Wall Street Journal article identifies "control" as an important motive for vertical acquisitions for firms in diverse industries. Live Nation seeks to buy Ticketmaster to have greater control over event promotion and ticketing; PepsiCo purchases Pepsi Bottling Group to capture greater control over beverage distribution; and Boeing merges with Vought Aircraft to gain greater control over manufacturing (Worthen, et.al., 2009). Such claims beg the question why contractual measures failed to provide the requisite "control" for buyers.

The recent flurry of vertical mergers and the awarding of a Nobel Prize in economics to Oliver Williamson in 2009 present a propitious opportunity to assess the explanatory power of economic theory in depicting the vertical boundaries of firms. In looking at these recent mergers, a cogent theory would be able to explain why above firms found pre-merger contractual relationships unsatisfactory while being able to describe how integration addressed those shortcomings. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Dynamic Transaction Costs and Firm Boundaries in the Soft Drink Industry
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.