Higher-Education Accreditation Market Regulation or Government Regulation?

By Hall, Joshua | Independent Review, Fall 2012 | Go to article overview

Higher-Education Accreditation Market Regulation or Government Regulation?


Hall, Joshua, Independent Review


In recent public debates regarding higher education, considerable attention has been paid to the general accreditation of higher-education institutions. In 2006, for example, the so-called Spellings Commission issued a report that calls for significant changes in accreditation:

Accreditation, the large and complex public-private system of federal, state and private regulators, has significant shortcomings. Accreditation agencies play a gatekeeper role in determining the eligibility of institutions and programs to receive federal and state grants and loans. However, despite increased attention by accreditors to learning assessments, they continue to play largely an internal role. Accreditation reviews are typically kept private, and those that are made public still focus on process reviews more than bottom-line results for learning or costs. The growing public demand for increased accountability, quality and transparency coupled with die changing structure and globalization of higher education requires a transformation of accreditation. (U.S. Department of Education 2006, 15)

The commission also criticizes accreditation for maintaining the status quo. A later finding is that "[a]ccreditation and federal and state regulations, while designed to assure quality in higher education, can sometimes impede innovation" (16).

In this short article, I briefly explore accreditation in higher education and the extent to which it represents market regulation or government regulation. I look at the extent to which general accreditation of colleges and universities as practiced in the United States has emerged from the needs of students, colleges, and universities or has been planned from the top down. If accreditation is an emergent phenomenon, like a marketplace, then as social scientists we should be extremely skeptical of attempts to "fix" what may not be broken.'

The Demand for Quality Regulation

The quality of some goods and services is easier to observe than that of other goods and services. For example, it is fairly easy to determine a book's quality while thumbing through it in a bookstore. It is more difficult, however, to ascertain a physician's quality by seeing a picture of her in a white coat or speaking with her for a few moments. If consumers believe that certain qualities are desirable, but they cannot divine these qualities ahead of time, they may be willing to pay for regulation. Conversely, firms in product areas where quality is difficult to ascertain ahead of time may also demand regulation in order to assure consumers that their products are valuable or safe.

Like all investment decisions, the decision to invest in human capital is fraught with peril. As Williams College economist Gordon Winston puts it in a 1999 Journal of Economic Perspectives article, "People investing in human capital through a purchase of higher education don't know what they're buying-and won't and can't know what they have bought until it is far too late to do anything about it" (15). It seems obvious that potential students want some form of quality-and-assurance regulation to help ensure that they will receive what they purchase, within some range. In addition, colleges and universities want to convince students and their families that the institution is actually providing the good that students think they are purchasing. If students cannot ascertain whether a college or university is actually providing graduates with the knowledge, skills, and postsecondary experience that they claim to provide, students may not enroll, and colleges and universities may have difficulty in covering expenses.2

The Market for Quality Regulation in General

If consumers and producers value quality regulation, we expect that such regulation will be provided without government intervention. One prominent example of voluntary private quality regulation is Underwriters Laboratory (UL). UL is a private firm that tests electrical equipment, such as appliances. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Higher-Education Accreditation Market Regulation or Government Regulation?
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Welcome to the new Questia Reader

The Questia Reader has been updated to provide you with an even better online reading experience.  It is now 100% Responsive, which means you can read our books and articles on any sized device you wish.  All of your favorite tools like notes, highlights, and citations are still here, but the way you select text has been updated to be easier to use, especially on touchscreen devices.  Here's how:

1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
2. Click or tap the last word you want to select.

OK, got it!

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.