Solving the Realization Problem with a Consumption Tax: Reconsidering Andrews' Proposal

By Vladimirova, Iana | Fordham Journal of Corporate & Financial Law, April 1, 2013 | Go to article overview

Solving the Realization Problem with a Consumption Tax: Reconsidering Andrews' Proposal


Vladimirova, Iana, Fordham Journal of Corporate & Financial Law


Introduction

As the income gap between the rich and the poor widens, Americans have begun to demand reform.' The Occupy Wall Street movement is a recent reflection of the public's frustration.2 The lowering of the effective tax rate for the very rich to 1 8% in 2008 from 30% in 1995 is often cited as the main cause for the income gap.3 Tax experts, however, are aware that the drop in effective tax rates for the very rich over the years is only the tip of the iceberg; a much larger problem looms in the non-taxation of unrealized gains.4 Although the very rich generate a majority of their income from the appreciation of their assets like stocks, business interest, and real estate,5 the appreciation of that property can only be taxed when realized under the current law.6 Mark Zuckerberg, a co-founder and chief executive officer of the popular social networking service Facebook, is an example of this phenomenon.7 Some analysts estimated Mr. Zuckerberg's stake in Facebook to be worth as much as $28 billion before the IPO of the company.8 Mr. Zuckerberg will not be taxed on his stake in Facebook unless he disposes of his shares.9 If upon death, Mr. Zuckerberg bequeaths the shares to his heirs, his heirs will only pay tax upon sale of the stock only for the appreciation in value since Mr. Zuckerberg's death.10

Some call the realization rule '"the Achilles' heel' of the tax system, 'the root of many tax evils,' and . . . 'the most intractable problem in the income tax.'"" One explanation for the rule is the belief that unrealized gains cannot be employed for "separate use and benefit" unless realized,12 but the reality is that there are ways for the wealthy to generate cash for consumption, completely tax-free, without ever needing to dispose of their assets.13 For example, Mr. Zuckerberg can simply use his stocks as collateral to borrow against, thereby avoiding tax liability while enjoying the fruits of his enormous unrealized wealth.14 This scenario is even more likely today, when the interest rates for the very rich have plummeted to almost 1%.15 Mark Zuckerberg's ability to avoid taxes on his enormous wealth is only a very recent example of how the very rich can take advantage of "Tax Planning 101."16

Thirty-five years after its first publication, William D. Andrews' seemingly radical approach, adopting a consumption-based tax system to solve the problem with the realization rule,17 draws renewed interest. The proposal provides simple solutions to the efficiency and equity problems of the realization rule without creating new complications.18 Unlike other proposals, Andrews' forgotten approach to solving the realization rule puzzle is simple and creates few undesirable consequences.19 Part I of this Note explores the historical and legal framework of the realization rule and its relation to income. In addition, Part I discusses the equity and efficiency problems of the realization rule and provides legal background for Andrews' proposal. Part II of this Note examines the numerous proposals that have emerged since the adoption of the realization rule. Moreover, Part II uses classic tax policy analysis to explain the equity and efficiency problems of the mark-tomarket, interest-on-tax, and retrospective taxation proposals. Part III of this Note explores Andrews' proposal in detail and explains why Andrews' consumption tax system effectively solves the realization rule problem. Part III also addresses critics' concerns of the consumption tax system.

I. A HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVE OF THE REALIZATION RULE PROBLEM AND ITS RELATION TO INCOME

Section A of Part I takes a historical look at how the realization rule became part of the definition of income. Then, Section ? explores the equity and efficiency problems that the realization rule creates. Section C examines several of the remedial proposals that have emerged in response to the realization rule. Finally, Section D provides historical background for Andrews' consumption tax proposal and explains why Andrews' proposal becomes relevant today. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Solving the Realization Problem with a Consumption Tax: Reconsidering Andrews' Proposal
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.