High Technology Competition: The Role of Higher Education and Research Infrastructure

By Puri, Yash R; Suchon, Kathleen | Advances in Competitiveness Research, January 1, 1997 | Go to article overview

High Technology Competition: The Role of Higher Education and Research Infrastructure


Puri, Yash R, Suchon, Kathleen, Advances in Competitiveness Research


INTRODUCTION

The past decade has seen considerable attention focused on competitiveness of U.S. firms in foreign markets. A wide body of literature on causes and consequences of global competitiveness has suggested a number of possible factors contributing to the diminished competitiveness of U.S. firms. Among others, studies by Baumol (1986), Jorgenson (1984), Plant and Welch (1984), Haveman and Wolfe (1984), Bishop (1989), and Kendrick (1980) have linked the U.S. education system to economic measures. As the discussion below shows, most of these studies have focused on secondary school systems. The role of scientists and engineers trained through the higher education system in enhancing the competitiveness of an economy has not been closely examined. These studies have assumed that productivity growth is the critical factor in competitiveness and therefore studied relationships of various factors to productivity growth. This study shows the impact of education on selected measures of competition in the high technology sector of an economy. As the U.S. economy increasingly moves towards a knowledge-based economy, this sector will play an increasingly important role in earning a high standard of living in the future. High technology industries provide the high value-added goods and services needed to ensure high wages which are necessary if the standard of living in the United States is to be maintained at a level competitive with other industrial countries.

REVIEW OF EARLIER STUDIES

In one of the early studies cited above, Baumol (1986) attributes the decline in the relative productivity growth rate in the U.S. to the phenomenon of convergence of productivity levels of various countries, concluding that the U.S. does not have a significant competitive problem. He suggests that though extraordinary investments or innovations in a country may be able to help a country sustain a higher productivity growth rate over a short run, the long run convergence in growth is inevitable due to the ability of other countries to imitate those innovations rather quickly. However, he observed no sign of convergence among the less developed countries and notes that "part of the explanation may well be ielated to product mix and education" (p. 1080). Although he points toward tle role of education when analyzing the phenomenon of declining productivity rates in relation to the third world countries, no formal analysis is included in the study.

Jorgenson (1984) clearly demonstrated that education has had an impact on U.S. productivity growth. In his study on the contribution of education to the economic growth of the U.S. from 1948 to 1973, approximately 11 percent of the economic growth during this period could be attributed to education. Plant and Welch (1984) also undertook a similar study and found a similar relationship. Jorgenson used a growth-accounting model to measure increases in productivity caused by education in terms of added earnings to individuals who received the education. His methodology treated labor with different education as inputs with different marginal productivity. Plant and Welch argued that inputs (labor and capital) used in the production of education could also be used to produce other goods and services. This opportunity cost to the economy in terms of the foregone goods and services is not accounted for in the growth-accounting moded. Therefore they used an alternative approach utilizing education as an intermediate factor in a surplus-accounting model, concluding that the contribution of education to the economic growth is significant, although their estimate of the contribution is smaller than that calculated by Jorgenson.

In a study of the effects of education on health, child care, and other nonmarket activities (which are also important elements of the standard of living), Haveman and Wolfe (1984) concluded that returns to education are not fully reflected in wage differentials. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

High Technology Competition: The Role of Higher Education and Research Infrastructure
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Welcome to the new Questia Reader

The Questia Reader has been updated to provide you with an even better online reading experience.  It is now 100% Responsive, which means you can read our books and articles on any sized device you wish.  All of your favorite tools like notes, highlights, and citations are still here, but the way you select text has been updated to be easier to use, especially on touchscreen devices.  Here's how:

1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
2. Click or tap the last word you want to select.

OK, got it!

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.