A Team Production Theory of Bankruptcy Reorganization

By LoPucki, Lynn M. | Vanderbilt Law Review, April 2004 | Go to article overview

A Team Production Theory of Bankruptcy Reorganization


LoPucki, Lynn M., Vanderbilt Law Review


This paper extends Professor Margaret Blair and Lynn Stout's pathbreaking Team Production Theory of Corporate Law to the bankruptcy reorganization of public companies. The paper begins by describing the prevailing contractarian theory of bankruptcy reorganization, the Creditors' Bargain Theory propounded by Professor Thomas Jackson in 1982. The paper briefly describes the Team Production Theory of Corporate Law and then projects the consequences of that theory for the firm in bankruptcy. The final part of the paper compares the Team Production Theory of Bankruptcy Reorganization with the Creditors' Bargain theory, reaching two conclusions. First, the Team Production Theory of Bankruptcy Reorganization describes the bankruptcy system more accurately than does the Creditors' Bargain theory. Second, if the empirical assumptions underlying the Team Production Theory of Corporate Law theory are accurate, the ex ante maximization recommended by the Team Production Theory of Bankruptcy Reorganization will better serve the goal of economic efficiency than the ex post maximization recommended by the Creditors' Bargain theory.

[S]ociety must insist on the maintenance of the "going concern" and must if necessary sacrifice to it the individual rights of shareholders, creditors, workers, and, in the last analysis, even of consumers.

- Peter Drucker1

I. INTRODUCTION

In the year before United Airlines filed for bankruptcy reorganization, the firm lost $3.2 billion.2 Fierce competition in the airline industry prevents United from stemming its losses solely through increases in revenues. Costs will have to be cut. The necessary expense reductions could come from reductions in employee pay and benefits, reductions in the amounts owing to creditors (which reduce interest expense), or both. Which should it be?

United's situation is complicated by the fact that its employees own 55 percent of its stock and that their wage levels are protected by a collective bargaining agreement.3 But if we assume those protections away, we reach a fundamental issue that has divided bankruptcy scholars for two decades: whose interests should bankruptcy reorganization serve?

The currently prevailing contractarian theories of the firm and of bankruptcy recommend cutting labor costs first. Bankruptcy, these theorists postulate, exists solely for the benefit of the creditors and shareholders of the firm. The theorists recognize that the interests of employees, suppliers, customers, and communities should be taken into account to the extent particular members of those constituencies are creditors with enforceable legal rights against assets under nonbankruptcy law. But they assert that to take any other interest of those constituencies into account would-as one writer put itconstitute "prima facie theft."4

The theorists' first premise derives from the agency theory of the firm. Shareholders own the firm. The board of directors, the managers, and the employees are the shareholders' agents, mere hired hands. When the firm is insolvent, ownership shifts to the creditors. In bankruptcy reorganization, the owners' interests, and theirs alone, are to be served. Debt, it follows, should be cut only as a last resortafter any possible cuts in labor costs.

Another group of bankruptcy scholars, sometimes referred to as "traditionalists," are of the less elegant view that bankruptcy exists to serve a variety of policies and therefore a variety of interests. Their answer to the hypothetical is that the losses should be shared among all interested parties, including creditors and shareholders. Because their arguments are noncontractarian and do not place economic efficiency first, they fall on deaf contractarian ears. The two groups talk past one another.5

In 1999, Professors Margaret Blair and Lynn Stout introduced a new and powerful contractarian theory of the public corporationone that only now is beginning to have its impact.

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

A Team Production Theory of Bankruptcy Reorganization
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Welcome to the new Questia Reader

The Questia Reader has been updated to provide you with an even better online reading experience.  It is now 100% Responsive, which means you can read our books and articles on any sized device you wish.  All of your favorite tools like notes, highlights, and citations are still here, but the way you select text has been updated to be easier to use, especially on touchscreen devices.  Here's how:

1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
2. Click or tap the last word you want to select.

OK, got it!

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.