Quantitative Theory and Econometrics

By King, Robert G. | Economic Quarterly - Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Summer 1995 | Go to article overview

Quantitative Theory and Econometrics


King, Robert G., Economic Quarterly - Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond


Quantitative theory uses simple, abstract economic models together with a small amount of economic data to highlight major economic mechanisms. To illustrate the methods of quantitative theory, we review studies of the production function by Paul Douglas, Robert Solow, and Edward Prescott. Consideration of these studies takes an important research area from its earliest days through contemporary real business cycle analysis. In these quantitative theoretical studies, economic models are employed in two ways. First, they are used to organize economic data in a new and suggestive manner. Second, models are combined with economic data to display successes and failures of particular theoretical mechanisms. Each of these features is present in each of the three studies, but to varying degrees, as we shall see.

These quantitative theoretical investigations changed how economists thought about the aggregate production function, i.e., about an equation describing how the total output of many firms is related to the total quantities of inputs, in particular labor and capital inputs. Douglas taught economists that the production function could be an important applied tool, as well as a theoretical device, by skillfully combining indexes of output with indexes of capital and labor input. Solow taught economists that the production function could not be used to explain long-term growth, absent a residual factor that he labeled technical progress. Prescott taught economists that Solow's residual was sufficiently strongly procyclical that it might serve as a source of economic fluctuations. More specifically, he showed that a real business cycle model driven by Solow's residuals produced fluctuations in consumption, investment, and output that broadly resembled actual U.S. business cycle experience.

In working through three key studies by Douglas, Solow, and Prescott, we focus on their design, their interrelationship, and the way in which they illustrate how economists learn from studies in quantitative theory. This learning process is of considerable importance to ongoing developments in macroeconomics, since the quantitative theory approach is now the dominant research paradigm being used by economists incorporating rational expectations and dynamic choice into small-scale macroeconomic models.

Quantitative theory is thus necessarily akin to applied econometric research, but its methods are very different, at least at first appearance. Indeed, practitioners of quantitative theory--notably Prescott (1986) and Kydland and Prescott (1991)--have repeatedly clashed with practitioners of econometrics. Essentially, advocates of quantitative theory have suggested that little is learned from econometric investigations, while proponents of econometrics have suggested that little tested knowledge of business cycle mechanisms is uncovered by studies in quantitative economic theory.

This article reviews and critically evaluates recent developments in quantitative theory and econometrics. To define quantitative theory more precisely, Section 1 begins by considering alternative styles of economic theory. Subsequently, Section 2 considers the three examples of quantitative theory in the area of the production function, reviewing the work of Douglas, Solow, and Prescott. With these examples in hand, Section 3 then considers how economists learn from exercises in quantitative theory.

One notable difference between the practice of quantitative theory and of econometrics is the manner in which the behavioral parameters of economic models are selected. In quantitative theoretical models of business cycles, for example, most behavioral parameters are chosen from sources other than the time series fluctuations in the macroeconomic data that are to be explained in the investigation. This practice has come to be called calibration. In modem macroeconometrics, the textbook procedure is to estimate parameters from the time series that are under study. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Sign up now for a free, 1-day trial and receive full access to:

  • Questia's entire collection
  • Automatic bibliography creation
  • More helpful research tools like notes, citations, and highlights
  • Ad-free environment

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Quantitative Theory and Econometrics
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.