International Encyclopedia of Public Policy and Administration - Vol. 2

By Jay M. Shafritz | Go to book overview

theory to model the funding process for a specific agency. This agency seeks ever-increasing budgets and can exploit perfect information about the legislature's preferences. The legislature has a standard demand function for the output of the agency: The lower the price, the higher the quantity desired. However, the legislature does not know the unit cost of the output from the agency. These assumptions allow the agency to submit an "all or nothing" ultimatum to the legislature, where the "all" is the maximum the legislature is willing to pay for an agency selected point along its demand function. Niskanen concluded that this agency always overproduces past the legislature's preferred level and past the socially optimal level. He further generalized that this situation produces a government that is always too large. Although this model serves as foundation for a body of literature, it has serious limitations. Niskanen clearly condensed a complex, iterative, and political process down to a small number of modeling assumptions. In doing so he left out critical aspects, such as the delineation between funding for agencies versus funding for programs, the role of the Office of Management and Budget (OMB), the existence of multiple principles for any agency action, and the role of agenda control within the legislature.

Niskanen's contribution serves primarily as a straw man architecture, which other scholars have used as a starting point. The ensuing work developed on this platform by incremental improvements in specific attributes: the addition of more complex budget options provided by Robert Mackay and Carolyn Weaver ( 1981), the inclusion of agency deception and legislative oversight from Jonathan Bendor , Serge Taylor, and Roland Van Gaalen ( 1985), and the provision of a dynamic, reiterative focus by Jonathan Bendor and Terry Moe ( 1985). There is also a current trend toward greater scope in formal models of bureaucracy beyond simply analyzing the budgetary dimension alone. For example, John Ferejohn and Charles Shipan ( 1990) concentrated on the policy output dimension but added judicial review and presidential veto to the model.

Another rich dimension of formal models of bureaucracy lies in the intersection of public administration and organizational theory. This class of models relies heavily on social choice theory, specifically, the principle of individual rationality: Individuals within a bureaucracy analyze alternatives and make decisions that maximize their own utility. The core idea is that organizational structure affects the aggregate behavior of the bureaucracy because the mechanisms for aggregating preferences are biased by individual preferences that are often expressed through informal, undocumented processes. Graham Allison ( 1971) has called these "action channels." Action channels have particular attributes: differing levels of individual power, definable jurisdictions, and specific historical precedents. Thomas Hammond ( 1986) applied this perspective to bureaucratic restructuring. Hammond asserted that organizational structures within bureaucracies behave like agendasetting structures within legislatures, and he constructed a simple model of hierarchy to demonstrate that agency heads can manipulate the final choice-set of the bureaucracy in order to maximize their individual utility. In the simplified version of the model there are field managers with specified jurisdictions who evaluate two policy alternatives and propose their own individual preferences to a middle manager. The middle manager takes the proposals from each of his or her subordinate field managers and submits a preferred alternative to the director. Hammond showed that the director can get a preferred choice-set simply by rearranging lines of reporting between the field managers and the middle managers. This situation infers that bureaucratic output is not necessarily an aggregation of participant preferences and leads to what Hammond calls the "structure = agenda" metaphor.

Formal models of bureaucracy provide a unique perspective to students of public administration. This approach, borrowing tools from economics, statistics, and formal logic, enables one to look at public institutions in a simplified manner. These models ask the question, What central underlying features exist across a broad range of institutional settings? This approach also contributes to the public administration literature by providing an abstract theoretical framework that is flexible enough to address a wide range of administrative relationships. However, the quality of these models and their conclusions is primarily a function of the quality of the stated assumptions. Critics of formal modeling commonly focus on the oversimplification of some model assumptions. Since this criticism has justly focused on the reliance upon the rational choice assumptions of individual utility maximization and perfect information, recent models have employed progressively more realistic and sophisticated specifications.

JEFF GILL


BIBLIOGRAPHY

Allison, Graham, 1971. Essence of Decision. Boston: Little, Brown.

Bendor, Jonathan, Serge Taylor, and Roland Van Gaalen, 1985. "Bureaucratic Expertise Versus Legislative Authority: A Model of Deception and Monitoring in Budgeting". American Political Science Review 79 (December): 1051-1060

Bendor, Jonathan, and Terry Moe, 1985. "An Adaptive Model of Bureaucratic Politics". American Political Science Review 79 (September): 755-774.

Ferejohn, John A., and Charles R. Shipan , 1990. "Congressional Influence on Bureaucracy". Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 6 (special issue): 1-44.

Hammond, Thomas, 1986. "Agenda Control, Organizational Structure and Bureaucratic Politics". American Journal of Political Science 30 (May): 379-420.

Mackay, Robert J., and Carolyn L. Weaver, 1981. "Agenda Control by Budget Maximizers in a Multi-Bureau Setting". Public Choice, vol. 36, no. 3: 447-472.

Niskanen, William, 1971. Bureaucracy and Representative Government. Chicago: Aldine-Atherton.

-923-

Notes for this page

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Project items

Items saved from this book

This book has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this book

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this page

Cited page

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited page

Bookmark this page
International Encyclopedia of Public Policy and Administration - Vol. 2
Table of contents

Table of contents

Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger
Search within

Search within this book

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Full screen
/ 1240

matching results for page

Cited passage

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Sign up now to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

"Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited passage

Welcome to the new Questia Reader

The Questia Reader has been updated to provide you with an even better online reading experience.  It is now 100% Responsive, which means you can read our books and articles on any sized device you wish.  All of your favorite tools like notes, highlights, and citations are still here, but the way you select text has been updated to be easier to use, especially on touchscreen devices.  Here's how:

1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
2. Click or tap the last word you want to select.

OK, got it!

Thanks for trying Questia!

Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

For full access in an ad-free environment, sign up now for a FREE, 1-day trial.

Already a member? Log in now.