Inflation Targeting: Should the Federal Reserve in Its Conduct of Monetary Policy Follow the European Central Bank and Adopt Some Form of Inflation Target Range? TIE Asked Thirteen Distinguished Experts

The International Economy, Winter 2004 | Go to article overview

Inflation Targeting: Should the Federal Reserve in Its Conduct of Monetary Policy Follow the European Central Bank and Adopt Some Form of Inflation Target Range? TIE Asked Thirteen Distinguished Experts


Some argue that while Fed Chairman Alan Greenspan, in office since 1987, has been an extraordinarily subtle and skillful manager, his successor may not enjoy these unique skills. Thus, the system needs eventually to agree on a series of guiding benchmarks if not a target for use in the conduct of monetary policy. Globally, such an additional tool might help in the convergence process and potentially create more stability for exchange rates.

Others counter that it is not wise to lock the system into a simplistic rule, or set of rules, particularly at a time of continued geopolitical uncertainty. Still others counter that the European Central Bank established provisions that have successfully anticipated such external shocks to the system.

Is the time approaching for the U.S. central bank to adopt an inflation target or inflation target range? Or does the U.S. monetary system require a more pragmatic and intuitive approach? To what extent should an inflation target be discretionary?

MILTON FRIEDMAN Senior Research Fellow, Hoover Institution, and recipient, 1976 Nobel Memorial Prize for Economic Science

Central banks the world over performed badly prior to the mid-1980s not because they lacked the capacity to do better, but because they pursued the wrong goals according to the wrong theory. Once they recognized that inflation is a monetary phenomenon and accepted price stability as their primary goal, there was a major improvement in performance. Since the mid-1980s, inflation has been decidedly lower and less volatile than earlier. That has been true for monies issued both by central banks that adopted explicit inflation targets and for those, like the U.S. Federal Reserve, that did not. Inflation targets are clearly not a necessary ingredient of a good central bank policy yet they are highly attractive as a means of codifying the responsibilities of central banks and enhancing their accountability.

OTMAR ISSING Member of the Executive Board, European Central Bank

It is, of course, a source of satisfaction to me that the European Central Bank--after only five years of operation--is mentioned as a possible model for other central banks to follow. At the same time I have always been convinced that there is no unique, universal recipe for successful monetary policy. The institutional environment and the major characteristics of economies differ substantially. In any case we would not give advice, especially not in public, on what other central banks should or should not do.

I will therefore simply sketch out what has worked well for us at the ECB. We announced our monetary policy strategy in October 1998. As a new institution responsible for a new currency area, the ECB decided not to simply copy an existing strategy, such as monetary targeting or inflation targeting. Instead we developed our own approach, best suited to our particular challenges.

The main elements of the ECB's strategy are the announcement of a quantitative definition of price stability and a two-pillar framework for the analysis of risks to price stability. The two pillars consist of economic analysis, which looks at the determinants of short-to-medium term price developments, and monetary analysis, which focuses on the monetary factors driving inflation at longer horizons. This two-pillar framework facilitates the systematic cross-checking of information from complementary analytical perspectives.

The ECB's definition of price stability--year-on-year increases in the Harmonized Index of Consumer Prices of below 2 percent--provides a firm anchor for expectations and a clear benchmark for accountability. In the context of our evaluation of our strategy in May 2003, we have clarified that we aim at inflation rates below but close to 2 percent in order to underline that a sufficient safety margin against deflation is taken into account.

The ECB does not identify a specific policy horizon but aims at maintaining price stability over the medium term. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Inflation Targeting: Should the Federal Reserve in Its Conduct of Monetary Policy Follow the European Central Bank and Adopt Some Form of Inflation Target Range? TIE Asked Thirteen Distinguished Experts
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Help
Full screen

matching results for page

    Questia reader help

    How to highlight and cite specific passages

    1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
    2. Click or tap the last word you want to select, and you’ll see everything in between get selected.
    3. You’ll then get a menu of options like creating a highlight or a citation from that passage of text.

    OK, got it!

    Cited passage

    Style
    Citations are available only to our active members.
    Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

    1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

    Cited passage

    Thanks for trying Questia!

    Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

    Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

    Buy instant access to save your work.

    Already a member? Log in now.

    Oops!

    An unknown error has occurred. Please click the button below to reload the page. If the problem persists, please try again in a little while.