Brothers and Breadwinners: Legislating Living Wages in the Fair Labor Standards Act of 1938

By Mutari, Ellen | Review of Social Economy, June 2004 | Go to article overview

Brothers and Breadwinners: Legislating Living Wages in the Fair Labor Standards Act of 1938


Mutari, Ellen, Review of Social Economy


Abstract Attention to the implicit and explicit wage theories articulated by economic actors and embedded in public policy reveals the underlying social norms and values in specific historical and industrial contexts. The Fair Labor Standards Act of 1938 (FLSA), the first federal minimum wage legislation in the United States, legitimated and institutionalized the idea that living standards and workers' needs matter in setting wages. They matter not simply in generating labor supply, but as the basis for government intervention in market mechanisms. Rather than viewing market mechanisms and government regulations dichotomously, economic actors debating the FLSA treated both market mechanisms and socially defined living standards as legitimate elements of wage-setting. Wage regulations also, by necessity, must grapple with issues of identity, that is, which workers (especially as defined by class, gender, and race ethnicity) are deserving of particular living standards. Debates over the language in the FLSA reveal the contested nature of masculinity during the period of economic crisis in the 1930s. Advocates responded by defining a multiplicity of living wages corresponding with different living standards, as well as a multiplicity of strategies for achieving them.

Keywords: minimum wage, living wage, New Deal, gender, masculinity, economic policy

INTRODUCTION

Since the mid-1990s, coalitions of community groups, faith-based activists, and labor unions have worked to pass legislation called municipal "living wage ordinances," mandating that private businesses receiving public funds pay their own workers a "living wage" higher than the current federal minimum wage. The emphasis of the 1996 Personal Responsibility and Work Opportunity ("welfare reform") Act on labor market activity as the primary means of provisioning for single mothers, along with concerns about economic inequality and the privatization of public services, have provided support for the contemporary living wage movement. The dollar threshold typically sought is the hourly rate equivalent for one full-time earner to keep a family of three or four above the federal poverty line; the legislated compromise is usually lower, attempting to balance the family-sustaining threshold with the political realities of negotiating with local governments.

Living wage activists have revived arguments that firms whose employees are among the working poor are parasitic, linking this argument to the rise in what has been called corporate welfare. If private sector employers receive tax subsidies and other benefits from state and local government, then those same employers have a social obligation to pay employees a family-sustaining wage. Current living wage initiatives can therefore be seen as attempts to assert a view of economic activity as a process of provisioning, that is, of producing and reproducing human material life. Such policies give community interests and well-being primacy over market forces.

The context of these contemporary living wage campaigns is quite different than the context under which the first federal minimum wage was passed. The enactment of federal wage and hour legislation during the New Deal was significant on many levels. The Fair Labor Standards Act (FLSA) set the first federal minimum wage and established a 40-hour week as a social norm by mandating a higher overtime rate of pay for hourly wage workers. Beyond the concrete policy precedents it established, the FLSA was symbolically important. The symbolic importance of the minimum wage has kept it at the forefront of policy debates even as actual coverage under the policy has waxed and waned (Waltman 2000).

Nevertheless, there are threads of continuity. Living wage movements, past and present, provide an alternative theory of wages to the orthodox view of wage floors as rigid barriers to finding market equilibrium. Establishing a federal minimum wage legitimated the idea that living standards and workers' needs mattered in setting wages. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Brothers and Breadwinners: Legislating Living Wages in the Fair Labor Standards Act of 1938
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Help
Full screen

matching results for page

    Questia reader help

    How to highlight and cite specific passages

    1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
    2. Click or tap the last word you want to select, and you’ll see everything in between get selected.
    3. You’ll then get a menu of options like creating a highlight or a citation from that passage of text.

    OK, got it!

    Cited passage

    Style
    Citations are available only to our active members.
    Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

    1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

    Cited passage

    Thanks for trying Questia!

    Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

    Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

    Buy instant access to save your work.

    Already a member? Log in now.

    Oops!

    An unknown error has occurred. Please click the button below to reload the page. If the problem persists, please try again in a little while.