Marxian and Post-Keynesian Theories of Finance and the Business Cycle

By Evans, Trevor | Capital & Class, Summer 2004 | Go to article overview

Marxian and Post-Keynesian Theories of Finance and the Business Cycle


Evans, Trevor, Capital & Class


Introduction

The end of the economic expansion that began in the us and the other advanced capitalist countries in the early 1990s presents an opportune moment to review Marxian theories of the business cycle. (1) Much of the orthodox discussion about whether the end of the expansion would lead to a recession has been informed by a neo-classical approach to economics, which conceives of recessions as the result of 'shocks' or 'disturbances' which lead an economy to deviate from a normal path of steady growth. In contrast, the Marxian approach sees business cycles as an intrinsic feature of the way that growth occurs in a capitalist economy.

According to this view, economic expansion occurs in protracted spurts, which lead to an accumulation of tensions, and a downturn in the business cycle is seen as the mechanism by which such tensions are eliminated, thereby creating the basis for a new period of growth.

Marx himself was, of course, one of the first people to recognise the existence of business cycles. (2) However, as has often been pointed out, there is no place in which he set out all the different elements of his approach in a consistent form. Since Marx's time, the Marxian theory of the business cycle has generated an enormous body of literature, and this received a fresh impetus in the early 1970s, when the lengthy period of relatively sustained accumulation that had begun after the Second World War came to an end. However, much of this literature is marked by having taken just one aspect of Marx's approach, and presented it as the over-arching explanation for business cycles. Furthermore, relatively little attention has been paid to financial aspects of the business cycle, even though Marx's own approach involved an interaction of real and financial factors. Indeed, because in Marx's time the downturn in a business cycle was usually associated with a dramatic monetary and financial crisis, he sometimes used the term 'crisis cycle', or even just 'crisis', when he was referring to the analysis of the business cycle. (3)

The aim of this paper is, first, to outline the basis of Marx's approach to the business cycle, and then to look at how more recent authors have attempted to use and develop this approach to understanding the modern business cycle. Marx's approach to business cycles can be viewed as consisting of three stages. The first of these is concerned to demonstrate that crises are a possibility in a monetary economy. This is considered in section 2.

The second stage is found in the course of Marx's analysis of production and circulation in a capitalist economy. Having demonstrated that a commodity economy involves the possibility of crises, Marx argues that, in a capitalist commodity economy, periods of profitable accumulation necessarily tend to undermine profitability, and that this blunts both the desire and the ability of capitalist enterprises to promote further accumulation. The different factors that Marx mentions in this connection, together with more recent interpretations by other Marxist writers, are reviewed in section 3.

The third and final stage of Marx's approach is concerned with the question of why a decline in profitability should lead not merely to a slowdown in accumulation, but to a period in which economic activity contracts. The answer has to do with the operation of the capitalist financial system, and the way it interacts with industrial and commercial capital. In order to understand this it is necessary, first, to analyse the credit system and the way the rate of interest is determined, and this is the subject of section 4. It is then necessary to examine how the availability of credit and the rate of interest impinge on the process of accumulation, and this is considered in section 5.

Marx's analysis of the financial system attaches considerable importance to institutional structures, and these have obviously changed considerably since his day. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Marxian and Post-Keynesian Theories of Finance and the Business Cycle
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Help
Full screen

matching results for page

    Questia reader help

    How to highlight and cite specific passages

    1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
    2. Click or tap the last word you want to select, and you’ll see everything in between get selected.
    3. You’ll then get a menu of options like creating a highlight or a citation from that passage of text.

    OK, got it!

    Cited passage

    Style
    Citations are available only to our active members.
    Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

    1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

    Cited passage

    Thanks for trying Questia!

    Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

    Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

    Buy instant access to save your work.

    Already a member? Log in now.

    Oops!

    An unknown error has occurred. Please click the button below to reload the page. If the problem persists, please try again in a little while.