An Ecology of Agency Arrangements: Mortality of Savings and Loan Associations, 1960-1987

By Rao, Hayagreeva; Nielsen, Eric H. | Administrative Science Quarterly, September 1992 | Go to article overview

An Ecology of Agency Arrangements: Mortality of Savings and Loan Associations, 1960-1987


Rao, Hayagreeva, Nielsen, Eric H., Administrative Science Quarterly


Press.

Hannan, Michael T., and John Freeman 1977 "The population ecology of organizations." American Journal of Sociology, 82: 929-964.

1989 Organizational Ecology. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University.

Haveman, Heather 1992 "Between a rock and a hard place: Organizational change and performance under conditions of fundamental environmental Economic activity is characterized by a multitude of agency relationships: Individuals and organizations known as principals delegate resources and tasks to other individuals and organizations known as agents, since they themselves lack time and expertise (Jensen and Meckling, 1976; Shapiro, 1987), as for example, when individuals delegate to their accountants the task of filing tax returns. Agency arrangements enhance role specialization in a society, connect actors across group boundaries and physical distances, and improve collective action by principals (Luhman, 1979; Zucker, 1986).

Agency relationships may also be collectivized: Anonymous principals can reduce their risks by banding together and entrusting authority to agents who accomplish the tasks delegated to them (Mitnick, 1984). For example, stockholders of a joint-stock company collectively entrust their capital to be deployed efficiently by the managers of the company. Other examples of collectivized agencies include commercial banks, savings and loan associations, mutual savings banks, credit unions, and mutual funds. To assure themselves of reliable performance by agents, principals use diverse ownership arrangements, monitoring systems, and incentives; thus, collectivized agency relationships can take on a wide variety of organizational forms (Jensen and Meckling, 1976; Fama, 1980). In this paper we ask whether organizations with different ways of organizing collectivized agency relationships encounter different survival prospects.

The paper is motivated by three considerations. First, studies of the differential survival of collectivized agency relationships extend the ecological perspective on organizational diversity. Ecological theory frames organizational change as a population-level process consisting of the replacement of existing organizations by new organizations and depicts selection as the mechanism that regulates organizational diversity (Hannan and Freeman, 1977, 1989; Aldrich, 1979; McKelvey, 1982). Despite a vigorously expanding body of research, ecological research on diversity has been criticized for emphasizing issues of specialism-generalism and for failing to examine differences in the survival of different ownership structures (Aldrich and Marsden, 1988: 58; Meyer and Zucker, 1989: 71). Two studies, by Barnett and Carroll (1987)and Barnett (1990), examined the survival of mutual and commercial telephone companies; however, they ascribed the survival of these ownership arrangements to their specialized roles in a technical system. By contrast, we seek to trace the survival of different ownership structures to differences in their governance systems and capital structures.

Second, attempts to connect the survival of agency arrangements to differences in their governance arrangements and capital structures provide an opportunity to link ecological theory with organizational economics. Transaction cost economics, property rights theory, and agency theory also hold that selection processes shape the survival of organizational forms. However, all three perspectives emphasize efficient monitoring and incentives as central to the survival of organizations (Alchian and Demsetz, 1972; Fama and Jenson, 1983a; Williamson, 1975). By contrast, ecological theory holds that although efficiency issues affect organizational change, their impact is constrained by institutional processes such as legitimacy (Hannan and Carroll. 1992). Nonetheless, studies of how population-level change is jointly shaped by efficiency considerations and institutional processes are absent in the literature and sorely needed (Hannan and Freeman, 1989: 339). …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

An Ecology of Agency Arrangements: Mortality of Savings and Loan Associations, 1960-1987
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Help
Full screen

matching results for page

    Questia reader help

    How to highlight and cite specific passages

    1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
    2. Click or tap the last word you want to select, and you’ll see everything in between get selected.
    3. You’ll then get a menu of options like creating a highlight or a citation from that passage of text.

    OK, got it!

    Cited passage

    Style
    Citations are available only to our active members.
    Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

    1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

    Cited passage

    Thanks for trying Questia!

    Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

    Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

    Buy instant access to save your work.

    Already a member? Log in now.

    Author Advanced search

    Oops!

    An unknown error has occurred. Please click the button below to reload the page. If the problem persists, please try again in a little while.