Regionalism and Layered Governance: The Choice of Trade Institutions

By Yarbrough, Beth V.; Yarbrough, Robert M. | Journal of International Affairs, Summer 1994 | Go to article overview

Regionalism and Layered Governance: The Choice of Trade Institutions


Yarbrough, Beth V., Yarbrough, Robert M., Journal of International Affairs


Those of us trained in the post-Second World War period, particularly in the United States, grew accustomed to a world in which the key elements of international relations -- security and trade -- were organized in particular ways. In the security sphere, we were accustomed to bipolarity, under which two well-armed superpowers faced each other, backed by incongruous political-economic systems. In the trade sphere, we were accustomed to what we might call exclusionary multilateralism. The trading system operated under a set of multilateral rules, embodied in the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT). However, the GATT was basically a Western group, excluding the Soviet Union and most of Eastern Europe.

Dramatic evidence suggests the realignment of both systems during the last decade. The changing face of Eastern Europe and the demise of the Soviet Union ended bipolar rivalry as we had known it. In trade, new forms of preferential agreements, often called regionalism, bilateralism or minilateralism, now play major roles alongside the GATT. In other words, basic international institutions (or what we might call polarity in the security sphere and lateralism in the trade sphere) have changed.

In response, we hear both sighs of relief and warnings of doom. This mixed response should not come as a surprise given the complex roles of economic, political and social institutions. Bipolar rivalry frequently led the superpowers to intervene in conflicts, but that same rivalry made small wars less frequent and bloody by containing lesser powers and ethnic nationalism.(2) With the end of bipolarity have come regional conflicts -- in Central Asia, Eastern Europe and Africa, along with greater uncertainty about who is responsible for dealing with them. With countries and regions no longer in the camp of one superpower or another, the postwar norms for intervention in civil wars also seem inadequate: Somalia, Cambodia, Kurdish Iraq and the former Yugoslavia are examples.(3) The status quo no longer seems to merit aggressive support as a Schiellingesque focal point for avoiding disaster.

In the trade sphere, the GATT process under U.S. hegemonic leadership resulted in a dramatic lowering of tariff barriers during the postwar period, and international trade burgeoned. Many critics complain, however, that the GATT's focus on tariffs merely encouraged countries to adopt less obvious but more pernicious nontariff barriers. The most ardent devotees of postwar trade institutions such as the GATT now seem to value these institutions and their norms as an end rather than a means of achieving or maintaining liberal trade. They consider departures from postwar institutions or from their underlying norms (especially nondiscriminatory multilateralism) illegitimate. At the other extreme, some scholars see the postwar trade institutions, never more than means to an end, as now overextended, inadequate, tired or outdated.(4) They believe that alternatives such as regionalism may complement, supplement or even take the place of the postwar institutions.

Many theories with which economists and political scientists work are ill-suited to analyze whether and how new institutions should be developed.(5) One approach accepts the form of institutions (such as polarity in security or lateralism in trade) as given or exogenous. These are seen as contexts in which the world finds itself, and the scholar's or policy maker's job is to discover each context's implications. Such theories tend to view relationships between polarity or lateralism and other variables (for example, stability, peace or openness) as timeless. They lead their followers to search for time-invariant answers to questions such as: Are bipolar or multipolar systems more stable? How does preferential trade affect efficiency? Does multilateralism limit protectionism? Is trade regionalism incompatible with openness?

The second approach is more normative. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items

Items saved from this article

This article has been saved
Highlights (0)
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

Citations (0)
Some of your citations are legacy items.

Any citation created before July 30, 2012 will labeled as a “Cited page.” New citations will be saved as cited passages, pages or articles.

We also added the ability to view new citations from your projects or the book or article where you created them.

Notes (0)
Bookmarks (0)

You have no saved items from this article

Project items include:
  • Saved book/article
  • Highlights
  • Quotes/citations
  • Notes
  • Bookmarks
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Cited article

Regionalism and Layered Governance: The Choice of Trade Institutions
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Help
Full screen

matching results for page

    Questia reader help

    How to highlight and cite specific passages

    1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
    2. Click or tap the last word you want to select, and you’ll see everything in between get selected.
    3. You’ll then get a menu of options like creating a highlight or a citation from that passage of text.

    OK, got it!

    Cited passage

    Style
    Citations are available only to our active members.
    Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA, APA and Chicago citation styles.

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

    1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

    Cited passage

    Thanks for trying Questia!

    Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

    Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

    Buy instant access to save your work.

    Already a member? Log in now.

    Author Advanced search

    Oops!

    An unknown error has occurred. Please click the button below to reload the page. If the problem persists, please try again in a little while.