Product Durability Choice

By Goering, Gregory E.; Pace, R. Kelley | Atlantic Economic Journal, December 1994 | Go to article overview

Product Durability Choice


Goering, Gregory E., Pace, R. Kelley, Atlantic Economic Journal


Economists differ on whether market structure affects product durability and, consequently, on whether planned obsolescence strategies pay. For example, Swan [AER, 1970] finds market structure does not affect product durability. However, Bulow [QJE, 1986] argues imperfectly competitive firms which sell their output will choose socially sub-optimal durability (planned obsolescence). The literature which assumes each firm exhibits Cournot behavior has devoted surprisingly little attention to the form of conjectures and the choice variable employed. In a simple two-period framework, the authors show that firm behavior can lead to: (1) inefficient durability as in Bulow or (2) socially optimal durability as in Swan. Whether firms engage in planned obsolescence depends upon firm behavior within the industry and not upon market structure per se as often proxied for by the number of firms.

Let [Beta] represent a discount factor and N [is greater than] 1 equal the number of firms in the industry. Suppose that firm i's first and second period output are given by [q.sub.1i] and [q.sub.2i], respectively. For simplicity, assume constant, symmetric conjectural variations:

v = [Delta][q.sub.2j]/[Delta][q.sub.2i](i [is not equal to] j).

Let [c.sub.1]([D.sub.i]) and [c.sub.2] represent the marginal production costs for firm i in periods one and two, where [c.sub.1]([D.sub.i]) is strictly convex in product durability [D.sub.i]. In symmetric subgame perfect equilibria, the maximization of a selling firm's two-period discounted profits [[Pi].sub.i], with respect to the firm's product durability [D.sub.i], then implies (ignoring firm subscripts):

[Delta][Pi]/[Delta]D = [q. …

The rest of this article is only available to active members of Questia

Already a member? Log in now.

Notes for this article

Add a new note
If you are trying to select text to create highlights or citations, remember that you must now click or tap on the first word, and then click or tap on the last word.
One moment ...
Default project is now your active project.
Project items
Notes
Cite this article

Cited article

Style
Citations are available only to our active members.
Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA 8, MLA 7, APA and Chicago citation styles.

(Einhorn, 1992, p. 25)

(Einhorn 25)

(Einhorn 25)

1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

Note: primary sources have slightly different requirements for citation. Please see these guidelines for more information.

Cited article

Product Durability Choice
Settings

Settings

Typeface
Text size Smaller Larger Reset View mode
Search within

Search within this article

Look up

Look up a word

  • Dictionary
  • Thesaurus
Please submit a word or phrase above.
Print this page

Print this page

Why can't I print more than one page at a time?

Help
Full screen
Items saved from this article
  • Highlights & Notes
  • Citations
Some of your highlights are legacy items.

Highlights saved before July 30, 2012 will not be displayed on their respective source pages.

You can easily re-create the highlights by opening the book page or article, selecting the text, and clicking “Highlight.”

matching results for page

    Questia reader help

    How to highlight and cite specific passages

    1. Click or tap the first word you want to select.
    2. Click or tap the last word you want to select, and you’ll see everything in between get selected.
    3. You’ll then get a menu of options like creating a highlight or a citation from that passage of text.

    OK, got it!

    Cited passage

    Style
    Citations are available only to our active members.
    Buy instant access to cite pages or passages in MLA 8, MLA 7, APA and Chicago citation styles.

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn, 1992, p. 25).

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences." (Einhorn 25)

    "Portraying himself as an honest, ordinary person helped Lincoln identify with his audiences."1

    1. Lois J. Einhorn, Abraham Lincoln, the Orator: Penetrating the Lincoln Legend (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1992), 25, http://www.questia.com/read/27419298.

    Cited passage

    Thanks for trying Questia!

    Please continue trying out our research tools, but please note, full functionality is available only to our active members.

    Your work will be lost once you leave this Web page.

    Buy instant access to save your work.

    Already a member? Log in now.

    Search by... Author
    Show... All Results Primary Sources Peer-reviewed

    Oops!

    An unknown error has occurred. Please click the button below to reload the page. If the problem persists, please try again in a little while.